Review
of:
Catherine
Mann, Is the US Trade Deficit Sustainable?
Washington, D.C.: Institute for
International Economics,1999.
by Diana Thorburn
December 17, 1999
Catherine Mann attempts to answer
one of the most critical and complex questions in US politics and international
economics: “Is the US trade
deficit sustainable?” While Mann’s objective is to analyze the “sustainability”
of the US trade deficit, vis-à-vis four areas, international trade and finance,
increasing global economic integration, competitiveness and trade policy, and
the global economy, her discussion ends up answering many other related and
important questions. She does this through an assessment of “external and
internal forces,” their confluence, and the analysis of relevant empirical
data.
That the trade imbalance may not be
sustainable is brought into question by the experience of the past. Mann points
out the similarities between the current US economic
situation, and that of the mid-1980s, when there was an expansion of the US economy
followed by a large devaluation of the US currency.
Mann asks what, if any, are the differences between the present state of the US economy
with its large external imbalance, and the experience of the eighties. She
describes the US’ position in the world economy in the late 1990s—robust
growth, low unemployment and inflation in a context of financial crises in the
rest of the world—and estimates that the US can run its present level of
current account deficits for two to three more years, before there is a
1980s-type devaluation.
The book is not just about
answering the question posed in the title, however. Mann situates the US in the
world economy, and discusses the most pertinent features of the contemporary
global economic situation, and its policy implications. The discussion serves
not only to create a context within which the title question can better be
understood, but also aptly treats other issues relevant to US interaction with
the world economy, and the inferences of this interface for American workers,
consumers and policy makers. Mann very effectively begins each chapter with
pithy quotes from influential people or publications that are relevant to the
specific topic. These serve to remind the reader of the debate surrounding the
issues, and provide useful reference points with which one can evaluate Mann’s
arguments and recommendations.
Mann first tackles the conundrum
posed by the development of a federal budget surplus while the trade deficit
has worsened. The two were, until recently, known as the ‘twin deficits’, and
were thought to be inextricably linked. The two deficits were called ‘twins’
and linked to each other because they appeared to move together when plotted
over time, and because there appeared to be economic relationships common to
the two deficits. It was believed that common forces were driving both
deficits, principally the expansionary fiscal policy of the 1980s mixed with
tight monetary policy. Imports rose as the dollar appreciated, worsening the
current account imbalance. The prevailing knowledge then had been that the
current account deficit would be eliminated by balancing the federal budget,
but this has not proven true, as the federal budget now has a surplus, while
the current account deficit has only grown larger.
The present situation questions
whether the twinning of the two deficits may have been incorrect to begin with,
or if their twinning was correct until new and unpredictable external factors,
principally the weak or negative growth of US trading partners, changed the
dynamics of the linkage. These unforeseeable external factors would be the US’ growing
economy allowing it to import more, while its trading
partners’ economies not growing at the same rate. This has resulted in the lack
of concomitant demand for US exports in the rest of the world, while US demands
for imports has increased considerably. That is, the ‘untwinning’
of the current account and the fiscal deficits occurred because, on the
external side, the robustness of the US economy
has not been matched overseas. There is a domestic dimension that also
attributes to the diversion between the original pair: the diversion can be
accounted for by the fall in the savings rate and increased consumption as a
result of the healthy economy.
Mann then moves on the question of US
comparative advantage as a factor in the large trade deficit. She makes the
case that the US has a
comparative advantage in services, particularly in financial assets as the US market for
government bonds is very mature. The US, since
1975, has had a positive trade balance in services, while the negative trade
balance is due to increased imports of capital and consumer goods. Hence
increasing exports of services would assist greatly in improving the current
external imbalances. This would require, however, further liberalisation of
services in world trade. Again Mann makes the point of the advantages of liberalised trade and globalization for US
prosperity.
Mann’s focus on globalization and
its role in the growth of the US economy
and on the current account deficit brings her to evaluate the impact of trade
on the American worker. This is an extremely pertinent question in the wake of
the recent protests at the World Trade Organization conference in Seattle. Those
protests were premised on the polemical notion that trade hurts the American
worker. Mann’s analysis focuses not on how specifically changes in the trade
balance and changes in export and import flows affect the American worker.
This issue is extremely sensitive
in both the US (and
European) domestic political arena. The popular understanding of the
relationship between trade and the labour market is that increased trade
results in loss of jobs in the US, and/or
exerts downward pressure on the wage rate. While there is a theoretical
relationship between the loss of low-skilled
jobs as a result of trade, Mann argues that these losses would also occur were
there improvements in technology (implicitly stating that no one would protest
improved technology, yet the results are the same as with increased trade). She
also argues that, with trade, demand for skilled labour increases, therefore
the appropriate policies are not trade barriers, but retraining low-skilled
workers for higher skilled jobs; indeed, she states that trade barriers would
hurt Americans as a whole.
Continuing on the topic of trade,
the book then assesses the role of trade in prospects for sustainable long-run
growth. The discussion focuses on how the current dynamics of US trade with
the rest of the world have rendered the optimal situation of growth with low
inflation. The recent phase of US economic growth has not resulted in the
expected inflation that normally accompanies such growth; indeed, inflation has
fallen. While there are new factors involved that explain the lack of
correlation between these two theoretically and, up to now empirically linked
variables, the correlation has not permanently been eliminated. That is, there
has not been inflation with the current phase of US economic growth because the
appreciation of the US dollar kept import prices down, and slow growth overseas
has kept commodity prices low. Slow overseas growth has also put downward
pressure on export prices. None of these situations is permanent, however, and
inflation will resume the expected upward path with time, but it will not
return fully to the original pattern, as we know it from the Phillips Curve.
Globalization has resulted in greater competition at the international level,
and hence pricing, productivity growth, and research and development spending
has assumed much higher profiles in terms of what variables production
decisions are based on. The growth phase has also seen new investment in plant
and equipment, and greater prospects for hiring without running into capacity
constraints.
In this discussion, Mann emphasizes
once again that globalization and increased trade have changed some of the
fundamental dynamics of the US economy,
in ways that have been good for US workers and consumers, and that these gains
should be made clear to Americans.
In her analysis of unfair trade
practices and the external deficit, Mann takes on the argument that the US trade deficit
is in some measure owed to trade barriers in other countries. She rejects this
argument, as her data shows that few bilateral deficits can be attributed to
this explanation. Furthermore, altering bilateral trade balances is a much less
optimal policy than would be changing business profitability or the household
savings rate. Where trade negotiations can have a meaningful effect is at the
multilateral level, specifically in the services industry, a point that Mann
has made in other contexts in her work. Mann tackles this argument in an effort
to preclude the erection of trade barriers in response to demands for such
policies by those who believe that bilateral trade relationships are the cause
of the trade deficit. Mann counters this position in two ways: first, that
bilateral trade barriers are few and exert minimal effect on the trade deficit,
and two, that other policy actions comprise much more optimal strategies for
reducing the deficit than do bilateral trade negotiations.
The new global economy has
challenged conventional wisdom all around, and Mann continues to address the
new developments brought on by globalization in her book as she deals with the
apparent inconsistency between the notion of US competitiveness and the trade
deficit. That the US can be the most indebted country in the world at the same
time as it is the most competitive is confounding to most people, economists or
not. Mann tackles this paradox, stating that these two issues are, in the main,
discrete, and that the trade deficit is not a good measure of international
competitiveness. At the same time, however, Mann does contend that the trade
deficit has implications for the US
competitiveness, and that the imbalances reflected in the trade deficit could augur
inauspiciously for US
competitiveness. To avoid this, Mann advocates that the US keep
abreast of the changing demands of a global economy viz. education and
training, research and development, and particularly improvements in technology
and productivity.
Up to now, Mann has described and
analysed how the international economy has provided unprecedented benefits for
US consumers, who are enjoying extremely high levels of consumption, as a
result of the confluence of many of the different factors that Mann has
addressed. However, the trade deficit in the face of high consumption begs the
question, is the US living
beyond its means?
Mann’s answer is that, in some
regards, yes, the US as a whole
is spending beyond its means. However, much of this spending has gone into
purchases that will bring returns in the long run as the economy will continue
to grow. Nevertheless, the current spending patterns, to be maintained, rely on
the foreign savings and national wealth to continue growing; these are not
definite prospects, and hence other policies should be targeted, such as
increasing household savings rates, and trade negotiations to liberalize trade
in services. Moreover, when economic growth slows, households will borrow more
to maintain present high consumption levels, adding adversely to the trade
deficit.
The last topic Mann treats before
arriving at the original question posed in the book, is the role of capital
markets in the trade balance. Capital transactions today are largely
independent of trade transactions, and far exceed trade transactions, though
they are both driven by the fundamental, perennial economic forces of relative
prices, income, savings and investment. For Americans this means that “trade”
does not only mean imports and exports of tangible goods and services, but also
the movement of financial wealth. This implies, however, that stability in
terms of policies and expectations is crucial to reaping gains and avoiding
crises. While the US is in a
better position than most countries because the US dollar is practically a
universal currency, and because asset markets are deep, crises in asset markets
can have negative consequences for imbalanced goods markets.
In the concluding chapter of the
book, Mann directly answers the question that the book’s title asks, “Is the US external
deficit sustainable?” The rest of the book, in a sense, built up to this
question and her answer, preparing the reader, as it were, by providing a
backdrop to the US economy
and its relationship to the world economy.
Mann first defines sustainability
as “a stable state or stable path where the external balance generates no
economic forces of its own to change its trajectory. A sustainable external
balance is one in which the feedback relationships between the external balance
and the exchange rates and interest rates are relatively weak in comparison to
other macroeconomic forces that affect these asset prices.” This definition cannot have meaning without
context, however, and so Mann looks at sustainability from three perspectives,
that of the borrower (the US), that of
the lender (foreign creditors), and from the political perspective.
An important point to make is that
implicit in Mann’s definition of sustainability is a reduction in the trade deficit. That is, she foresees a continued
trade imbalance on the deficit side, but this imbalance will only continue to
generate positive effects if there is movement towards reducing it. Otherwise,
it appears that Mann is saying in her extrapolation from the data and events of
the mid-1980s, her analysis of current data, and the consideration of other
important factors such as the composition of trade and investment flows and the
rest of the world economy, a depreciation of the US dollar must take place, and
the current account imbalances will generate negative effects for US workers
and consumers.
From the US
perspective, defining sustainability requires evaluating a number of questions,
such as: do imbalances mean for the US what they
mean for other countries, given the US’ unique
position in the world economy? An example of why this question is important is
that while large trade imbalances have proved
economically disastrous for other countries in the past, those economies do not
enjoy the US’ influence
and position in the world economy, with such a powerful currency and such a
large and strong economy. These
questions are relevant, because for the borrower, the US, future
claims on the resources of the country depend on whether the imbalance is
sustainable or not. That is, will the deficit and the interest payments on it
grow so large that they impact negatively on future consumption? Or can
consumption levels be maintained, or increase, at the same time as the debt
burden can be maintained as required? This is what sustainability means for the
US.
From the investors’ perspective,
one must ask, how long are investors willing to hold on to US debt? Perhaps
were it any other country, investors may not want to hold on to debt for a long
time, but again the US is a special case, as US assets are considered valuable
for financial asset portfolios. But if investors were to become doubtful of the
US’ ability
to repay its loans, and decided to cash in, and the US were suddenly required to repay not only interest but
principal, this could create adverse shocks for the US economy.
Furthermore, should the deficit grow, will investors be willing to lend more to
the US?
Finally, from the political
perspective, Mann evaluates the sustainability of the trade deficit with
respect to the voting public. Can a political representative maintain support
with a trade imbalance such as this? Particularly when populist campaigns focus
on the deficit and propose protectionist measures as a solution? How long can
the present situation be sustained before the
electorate has had enough and votes in policy makers who promise to change the
situation (or at least promise to try
to change it)?
Mann then assesses the
sustainability of the trade deficit, and the “special-ness” of the US economy,
with three different tests, using the same basic data in three different but
possible scenarios.
In the first scenario, Mann keeps
the value of the US dollar stable, with US and world growth rates as they are
currently projected (US growth slowing a bit and the rest of the world picking
up a bit), and looks to the year 2010. This case suggests that the trade
deficit is sustainable for about three years, before the US consumer
starts to feel the effects of growth rates not matching the debt burden. At
this point the political sustainability may also come to an end. The investor,
in this scenario, probably would be willing to take up the US assets
that would become available to sustain the deficit, as growth resumes overseas,
and US additions to financial portfolios are sought.
Mann conditions this tentative
conclusion of unsustainability on the borrower side
by introducing the features of the US’
“special-ness”. She thus concludes further that the calculations used to arrive
at this conclusion may lose relevance in light of the fact that most of the US debt is in
US dollars, that US assets
enjoy particular attractiveness in international financial markets, and that a
depreciation of the dollar is unlikely. Nevertheless, even if in two or three
years the predictions of unsustainability do not
prove true, they will in the longer run.
The second scenario posits a
substantial depreciation of the dollar, a likely scenario should the trade
deficit prove unsustainable. Should this happen, the trade deficit will not
improve, and the sustainability problem will be postponed but not eliminated. US growth
would slow, the rest of the world’s growth would increase, and the deficit
would return to its original level in about five years, given a 25% depreciation. Further, inflation would increase, and
productivity would decrease.
The third scenario envisions
structural change having taken place, where the US dollar remains at high
value, and economic reforms have increased both world rates of growth and US growth rates,
via the liberalization and deregulation of world trade in services. This has
been Mann’s prescription throughout the book. In fact, this scenario, in
conjunction with education and training for American workers, would yield
positive results for all the controversial issues she raises in the book, such
as trade’s impact on the wages of low-skilled workers.
Finally, Mann raises the question
of the implications of the new European currency, the euro, for the trade
deficit. Primarily, the effects of the euro will be felt on the side of
investor sustainability, as euro assets may become more attractive and compete
with US assets. Should this happen, this will lower the sustainability limits
for the present external imbalance.
For the economy to correct its
external imbalances, US policy makers will have to make far-reaching changes to
the present import-export profile, changes that could entail difficult
adjustments domestically the longer they are put off. Changes will also have to
be made in the US domestic
savings rate, and the liberalization of global trade in services. Furthermore,
the depressions, and financial crises in the rest of the world will have to be
remedied so that the US can regain
buoyant trading partners so that US exports can resume growth.
In sum, Catherine Mann’s principal
conclusions are based on the fact that the globalization of the US economy
causes trade and domestic policy to converge, so that good policies in the new
millennium will balance both domestic and external needs and objectives. These
conclusions are:
(1)
International trade has been good for the US economy in
stimulating growth without inflation.
(2)
Globalization and its benefits must be sold to the
American people, and they ought to be better equipped to take full advantage of
the US advantage
in the global economy.
(3)
Without rectification of the financial crises in US
trading partners, the current account deficit will continue and become
unsustainable in 2-3 years.
(4)
Should the external imbalance become unsustainable, a
depreciation without domestic structural changes will not rectify the
imbalance, and may augur an increase in inflation
(5)
The liberalization of trade in services is the
critical factor to reduce the trade deficit.
(6)
Household savings levels are too low, and consumption
levels are too high; should the stock market boom ebb, household debt levels
will rise as households borrow to maintain high
consumption levels.
(7)
Growth in the rest of the world’s economies will
precipitate a narrowing of the current account gap, as investors would
diversify their portfolios to other countries that at present are not
attractive for investment.
The political aspect of this issue
is a crucial consideration to the question of what policy will work best to
maintain sustainability (and reduce the deficit). The policies likely to be
implemented should the electorate demand a change in the present set of policies, are likely to be protectionist trade policies that
will not be beneficial to US consumers. Other policies, such as a currency depreciation, will not in the medium or long term
solve the problem. Mann posits that political sustainability has already been
reached, at least initially, though one can foresee that it will really come to
a head when the deficit is no longer economically sustainable and consumption
is forced down.
Mann’s book makes a timely and
relevant contribution to the understanding of the question about the US trade
imbalance, and the conundrums related to it. But the book also provides a
description and assessment of the bigger picture of the US and the
world economy, and how the current state of globalization and world capitalism
is manifesting itself. The US trade
deficit is a product of the new global economy, and its sustainability or unsustainability are dependent not
only on domestic policy actions, but also on policies and developments in the
rest of the world. Certainly there are initiatives that the US can do
independently of the rest of the world, such as raise the domestic savings
rate, and concentrate on education and training for the future. But there are
policies and developments that the US has only
partial control over, or none at all. These include
liberalisation in the trade of services, a policy that would require the
collaboration of all WTO members.
Growth in the rest of the world’s
depressed economies is also necessary for sustainability, but besides financial
and technical aid transfers towards economic reform and rehabilitation in the
rest of the world, much of the rebounding necessary in other countries depends
on the domestic political economy, which is sovereign to that country. Where
the US has even less influence is in the future attractiveness of the euro,
which could have negative effects on the sustainability of the US current
account, as investors may become less willing to buy or keep US financial
assets.
Another important contribution of
this book is its methodology. By maintaining a consistent focus on both the
external and domestic factors, and also on their interaction, Catherine Mann’s
methodology appropriately reflects the new context of economic forces and their
dynamics, effects and outcomes. Treating any of these discretely would not
portray the entire picture necessary to understand contemporary developments in
the world economy in general, nor the question of external
balances in particular, and hence would not render viable or realistic
policy prescriptions. Having seen the aptness of the application of this
approach, one cannot see how future analyses of domestic or international economic phenomena could be otherwise carried out.
The points raised
in the book, and the conclusions drawn, bring one to reflect on the possibility
of the various scenarios. The possible scenarios as presented by Mann bring
into question the sustainability of the capitalist world economy, as well as
the implications of US economic
weakness on global political stability. Suppose that growth does not pick up in
the rest of the world? And, bearing in mind that the US is at present the
global hegemon, in large part due to the strength of
its economy, suppose the US continues to become more and more indebted, causing
the external imbalance to become unsustainable and rendering the US
economically weak—what will this mean for global peace and security? Clearly these questions are way beyond the
scope of the book, and it is no fault of Mann’s for not addressing them, but
they are important in the larger scheme of things. Indeed the clarity of Mann’s
analysis, and the disaggregation
of the causal factors critical to the present situation perhaps present the
necessary details for intervention to preclude such a scenario. If this is the
case, then whose responsibility is it to take the requisite measures proposed?
The audience of this book, and the receptiveness of that audience, would thus
become very important. The response to Catherine Mann’s arguments should thus
be greatly anticipated.