From the
Introduction: Traditional
interpretations of the oil-foreign policy nexus
In this paper I examine the relationship
between the rise and fall in oil prices and
The relationship between oil and
Oil as a foreign policy issue has
also been considered in the context of the Cold War, where, particularly in the
1980s, the
Background to US foreign policy in
Latin America
US foreign policy towards Latin America
has always had economic dimensions, implicit or explicit. During the first
century of US policy toward Latin America—from just before the region won its
independence from Spain in the early 1800s until the early 1900s—the objectives
of US foreign policy in the region were the fulfillment of America’s “manifest
destiny” through territorial expansion, and the precluding of European
influence and power in the region, a policy embodied in the 1823 Monroe
Doctrine.
Towards the end of the 19th
century, US policy shifted as decision-makers began to think of Latin America
as the seat of the US’ commercial empire. This shift precipitated the US
attempt to create an economic—not merely political—sphere of interest in the
region. This shift in strategy was based on two principal factors:
1)
Latin America was considered unsuitable for European
immigration and was already populated by undesirable races (Iberian, Indian,
African) that the US deemed unfit for incorporation into the US;
2)
A shift in the imperial contest where commercial
advantage was seen as a more worthwhile endeavour. This included the
realization that European-style imperialism was expensive, as evidenced by
British and French imperialism in Asia and Africa, in terms of military and
administrative outlays that required considerable resources with questionable
economic returns;
These policy ideas became embodied
in the 1888 Pan-American conference that led to the creation of the Commercial
Bureau of the American Republics, parent of the Pan American Union, the
precursor of the Organization of American States. Subsequently the US made a
series of bilateral reciprocity treaties with individual Latin American
governments.
The new enthusiasm for commercial
as opposed to political hegemony was made in the 1904 Roosevelt Corollary (to
the Monroe Doctrine), also known as the Big Stick policy. This policy stated
that if a country “behaves itself” it should not fear interference from the US,
but, should a country act in a way as improper, and intervention by another
nation results, the US may exercise force in its role as an international
police power. Thus the US claimed a general right to intervene in the
hemisphere, including its financial and economic problems. This claim was
extended by a still more expressly activist policy: Dollar Diplomacy.
Dollar Diplomacy was a policy
created by US president William Taft (term of office: 1909-13) and his
Secretary of State, Philander C. Knox, to ensure financial stability in Latin
America. While Dollar Diplomacy has been interpreted as the “heedless
manipulation of foreign affairs for strictly monetary ends,”[1]
one could argue that its intention of financial control was not only an
economic objective, but was, at least to some extent, politically motivated.
While it is true that the policy sought to protect and extend US commercial and
financial interests in the region, it also had the objective of precluding
European economic power in the region. At this time, commercial hegemony over
the region was held by England, France and Germany, which the US had a vested
interest in dismantling, not only in its contest for power in the region. As a
practical matter, European creditor nations tended to resort to military
intervention in order to collect on its debts in Latin America, which violated
the US’ proprietary senses. If the US wanted the Europeans out, it meant that
US banks had to move into the region in order to obviate European financial
presence there.
The Roosevelt Corollary
and subsequently the Dollar Diplomacy policy were issued in
response to German, Italian and British armed intervention in Venezuela when
its government defaulted on their debts in 1902. Subsequently, when the
Dominican Republic defaulted to its European creditors in 1904, the guarantee
of U.S. loans was exchanged for the right to choose
the Dominican head of customs (the country’s major revenue source). An
(unsuccessful) attempt was also made in Nicaragua to overthrow the president,
and then provide guarantees the new president for “friendly” US loans.[2]
The Dollar Diplomacy
policy sought to protect and extend US commercial and financial interests, and
it had the objective of precluding European economic power in Latin America. At
this time, it was England, France and Germany who held commercial hegemony over
the region. The US had an interest in dismantling that hegemony, not least
because European creditor nations tended to resort to military intervention to
collect their debts in Latin America, a practice that affronted the US’
proprietary sentiments. But if the US wanted the Europeans out, US banks would
have to move in to supplant the traditional lenders.
Dollar Diplomacy was seen as a
failure. The Taft administration abandoned it in 1912, and the following year
President Woodrow Wilson
publicly repudiated it. Nevertheless, the US continued to have a strongly
activist regional policy throughout the 20th century, until the end
of the Cold War.
Cold War Policy: Economic
Dimensions
After an all-too-brief “golden era”
of US-Latin America relations, during which Franklyn Delano Roosevelt
promulgated non-intervention under the Good Neighbour policy, followed by near
unanimous Latin American support for the Allies in World War Two (WWII), US
foreign policy in Latin America, as in the rest of the world, was dominated by
the anti-Communist effort of the Cold War. The success of the Cuban Revolution,
just 90 miles off the coast of Florida, reminded the US that Latin America was
the geographical region closest to home. US strategies to promote economic
development (and thus forestall) pro-Communist sentiment ranged from technical
and financial aid, to support for undemocratic, often repressive authoritarian
dictators, to direct albeit covert action to overthrow any leader perceived as
too friendly to Communism. The Iran-Contra scandal was perhaps the epitome of
this period, where the US used the proceeds from illegal arms sales to Iran in
order to fund (again illegally) US-trained guerrillas against the
democratically elected, pro-Socialist Nicaraguan government.
In economic terms, after WWII, the
US dominated the region. For most countries, at least one-third of their total
trade was with the US. Latin America was also an important market for US
exports: in 1950 some 28% of total US exports went to Latin American countries
(O’Brien 1999, ix). Private US investment was quite significant in some
countries, particularly Cuba, Brazil, Colombia, Peru, Chile and Venezuela. US
manufacturing enterprises, in their drive to expand their markets, saw Latin
America as a natural target. The transnational corporations allied themselves
with the IMF and local regimes to promote economic policies to enlarge the
consumer base (though, arguably, these alliances and any ensuing policies were
largely ineffectual.) Thomas O’Brien (1999) argues that, as far as US relations
with Latin America are concerned, the 20th century should be
remembered as the “corporate century”. His thesis is that US corporations
launched and sustained an “intensifying effort to transform Latin America into
a series of societies compatible with the successful operation of capitalist
enterprises” (vii). The conclusion is that the entirety of the US-Latin
American relationship in the 20th century has been driven by the
motive of US capitalist expansion.
Even if O’Brien’s thesis seems
overdrawn, there obviously were significant economic interests at work in the
US’s Latin American policy during the Cold War, even within the overarching
anti-Communist political thrust. Preserving and expanding capitalism was, after
all, a key element in the anti-Communist effort. It might be argued, however,
that these economic aspects were implicit in Cold War policy, rather than
economic motives in and of themselves.
Sometimes, however, the US’s
economic objectives were explicit. Often the rationale behind anti-Communist
covert action was to protect US business interests. For example, the
expropriation of property belonging to the US-owned United Fruit Company was a
significant issue in the decision making that culminated in the overthrow of
the democratically elected Guatemalan president, Jacobo
Arbenz, in 1954.[3]
Similarly, protecting US business interests in Chile was a good part of the
motive for assisting the coup that deposed democratically elected president
Salvador Allende in 1973.
The most expressly “economic”
policy of the Cold War relationship with Latin America was in the early 1960s,
and was driven primarily by the Cuban Revolution. President Kennedy argued that
if socio-economic conditions remained as they were in Latin America, Communism
would easily take hold of those countries wracked by poverty and deprivation.
This policy came into being as the Alliance for Progress, and comprised
technical and financial aid towards modernization and economic development.
After a decade with few, if any,
perceptible successes, the Nixon administration downgraded the project, and cut
financial aid to Latin America significantly. The US advised Latin America to
open its doors to private enterprise. US aid policy to the region reflected
this position. More than half US government money going to Latin America in the
1970s took the form of Export-Import Bank loans to US exporters in the region
(Stallings 1987, 100). Thus foreign policy towards the region through Carter
did not explicitly reflect economic concerns—the US’ or Latin America’s—to any
significant degree until the Reagan years. Nevertheless, there were implicit
economic dimensions to the US-LA relationship during that period, one feature
of which was the activity of US financial institutions in the region during the
1970s and 1980s.
US foreign economic policy towards
Latin America during the rise and fall in oil prices does not fit into the general
pattern of US-Latin America economic relations during the Cold War, but could
perhaps be interpreted in O’Brien’s terms: as one aspect of the quiet but
consistent thrust of official policy to expand American capitalism beyond US
boundaries. According to O’Brien’s thesis, these efforts were not limited to
the actions and initiatives of the US private sector: the US government
implicitly promoted the expansion of private financial entities in the region
during the 1970s, and in the early 1980s took direct measures on behalf of US
private sector interests to redress the fallout that followed when Latin
American governments went into default. Thus while not necessarily capital ‘F’
capital ‘P’ foreign policy, the relationship between US foreign policy and US
private economic interests’ activity in Latin America is a small aspect of the
“corporate century” that is worth exploring as an example of the linkages
between the US domestic economy and US policy towards other countries.
Oil prices, petrodollars and US
banks
There are two aspects of the US
relationship with Latin America, where oil is concerned. First is the
relationship with oil producing countries, namely Mexico, Peru and Venezuela,
where US oil companies had significant interests up until they were
respectively nationalized. The second aspect, which will be explored here,
deals with the recycling of petrodollars (the enormous oil profits of the OPEC
countries) in loans from US banks to Latin American countries.
American banks began expanding into
Latin America in the mid-1960s, after three decades of wariness of the region
(many countries had defaulted on their debts in the 1930s.) Latin American
economies were growing rapidly, and the presence of many multinational
affiliates was a bellwether of economic optimism in the region. US and European
business cycles were then on the downswing, stimulating the search for new
borrowers in order to maintain their loan volume and profit rates (Stallings
1987, 96). In the early 1970s, OPEC producers needed to do something with their
windfall from the rise in oil prices that resulted from the US support of
Israel in the 1973 Yom Kippur War, and deposited it primarily in branches of
US-based multinational banks (Wachtel 1977, 4).
Having gotten hold of these large sums of cheap money, these banks then sought
to make a profit by re-lending.
The political and economic
situation in Latin America was propitious for the taking of these low-interest
loans: In the late 1960s, largely influenced by the precepts of dependency
theory, Latin American governments initiated a policy of import substitution
industrialization (ISI). This strategy aimed to break the cycle of declining
terms of trade for Latin American primary products, and promote the production
of manufactured goods within national borders, with the ultimate aim of
realizing higher economic growth and development. To finance this strategy,
governments resorted to borrowing abroad from international lending
institutions and private commercial banks.
The doubling of oil prices in
1973-4 spurred further borrowing on the part of Latin American governments and
private sector interests to pay for higher-priced oil imports. At the same
time, the oil shocks hit US businesses adversely, further dampening loan demand
at home. A reduction in interest rates after 1976 accelerated borrowing even
further. The market for loans was competitive, and foreign commercial banks
vied vigorously with each other, under the assumption that governments were
risk-free borrowers, and would not default. The lucrativeness of the borrowing
business drew hundreds of smaller banks in the market, and borrowing became
even easier for Latin American countries.
When oil prices rose again in 1979,
after the fall of the Shah of Iran and the Islamic Revolution, again events in
which the US was intricately involved, the renewed global recession further
depressed commodity prices. Despite ISI, commodity exports still contributed
significantly to export earnings and national income in Latin America, and the
loss of income was a severe shock to many Latin American economies. In 1980,
the US Federal Reserve Board (the Fed) took steps to curb US inflation by
monetary tightening, part of which was a drastic increase in interest rates. By
1982 the government of Mexico announced it could not meet its external debt
obligations; subsequently many other Latin American governments followed suit,
and the Debt Crisis was born.
The US government’s involvement was
much less in the lending phase than in the subsequent crash-and-attempt-to-
recover phase. At the time of Mexico’s announcement, Latin American external
debt totaled about $315 billion. US banks held nearly 40% of that debt, with
the nine largest banks in the US holding two-thirds. Given this rather drastic situation,
and the fact that the US financial sector was at serious risk of collapse
should the loans not be repaid, the US was heavily involved in negotiating with
Latin American governments on debt repayment. The US acted through the IMF on
the one hand, and a consortium of private international banks on the other.
Government officials from the State Department, Treasury and the Federal
Reserve Board were key players in the planning and negotiating for debt
rescheduling. The end result was a series of precepts calling for drastic
structural economic reforms. These precepts have now come to be known as the
Washington Consensus. They were primarily designed to increase foreign exchange
revenue so that debts could be repaid.
There is also an “official” foreign
policy aspect of this story. Barbara Stallings (1987) argues that the banks’
activities served to vitiate official US foreign policy to Latin America during
the Carter administration (1976-80) in two ways. Jimmy Carter came into office
promising to focus on human rights issues around the world, including Latin
America, and to some extent he was successful in this policy.[4]
First, aid was cut off to the most repressive regimes in the region, while ties
were strengthened with more democratic governments. However, the large bank
credits continued to prop up many of the same authoritarian governments that
official policy sought to sanction. Second, where Latin American countries
accumulated heavy debt as a result of cheap and easily accessible bank loans, the
debt servicing obligations caused or exacerbated balance of payments problems.
Impending crises in borrower nations brought the involvement of the IMF,
stepping in to give short-term loans, along with the conditionalities
of cutting public expenditure. Stallings’ argument is that the types of
policies that the IMF imposed with their loans caused economic hardships and
often required political repression for their enforcement.
Conclusion
This short story has attempted to
make the link between (1) US foreign policy in the Middle East, (2) the
deposits of OPEC’s oil proceeds in US banks, (3) the US domestic economy, (4)
the activities of US banks in Latin America, and (5) the Latin American Debt
Crisis. OPEC had oil profits because it had raised prices to punish the US for
its assistance to Israel in the Yom Kippur War. The US domestic economy was in
a recession largely due to the rise in oil prices as well as to fiscal deficits
brought on by spending on the Vietnam War. As a result of the recession, US and
European demand for loans fell, and US banks began to look overseas to lend
money, and they looked to their “natural” market, Latin America. The recession
provided a further push for US banks to broaden their activity in Latin
America. At the same time, largely due to the development strategy being
pursued in Latin America, Latin American governments and private investors
borrowed at such a rapid pace that the market for loans to the region grew by
leaps and bounds. When oil prices rose again in the late 1970s, and US domestic
inflation soared, the Fed sought to cool the economy and decrease the money
supply, and drastically increased interest rates, which ultimately led to the
default on over $300 billion in loans, nearly 40% of which was from American
banks.
References
Atkins,
G. Pope. 1999. Latin America and the
Caribbean in the International System. Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press.
Conant, Melvin. 1982. The Oil Factor in
US Foreign Policy, 1980-90. A Council on Foreign Relations Book. Lexington,
Massachusetts: Lexington Books.
De Carmoy, Guy. 1977. Energy
for Europe. Washington, D.C.:American Enterprise
Institute.
Encyclopædia Brittanica. www.brittanica.com
Frieden, Jeffry. 1991. Debt, Development and Democracy: Modern Political Economy and Latin America,
1965-85. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press.
Griffin,
James, and David Teece. 1982. OPEC Behaviour and World Oil Prices. London: Allen and Unwin, with the Centre for Public Policy, University of
Houston.
O’Brien,
Thomas. 1999. The Century of US
Capitalism in Latin America. Albuquerque, New Mexico: University of New
Mexico Press.
Pastor,
Robert. Whirlpool: US Foreign Policy
toward Latin America and the Caribbean. Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton
University Press.
Smith,
Peter. 1996. Talons of the Eagle:
Dynamics of US-Latin American Relations. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Stallings,
Barbara. 1987. Banker to the Third World:
US Portfolio Investment in Latin America, 1900-1986. Berkeley, California:
University of California Press.
Wachtel, Howard. 1977. The New Gnomes:
Multinational Banks in the Third World. Washington, D.C.: Transnational
Institute.
[1] Encyclopædia Brittanica. www.brittanica.com
[2] This
policy was also attempted in
[3] The Guatemalan government put through a series agrarian reforms that empowered government to expropriate uncultivated portions of large plantations, valued according to its taxable worth. In 18 months 1.5 million acres were distributed to some 100,000 families. The United Fruit Company immediately opposed the reforms as it owned enormous tracts of Guatemalan land, 85% of which was unused (the company maintained it was held in reserve for natural disasters.) The UFC had also consistently undervalued its holdings when calculating its taxes, thus the value placed on it, according to its own valuations, was much lower than its true value. Also worth noting are the personal ties between UFC and Washington as Secretary of State John Foster Dulles and CIA director Allen Dulles both worked for a law firm that had close ties to UFC.
[4] The ending of atrocities committed by the Argentine military dictatorship, and the freeing of political prisoners in Cuba and Paraguay have been in large part attributed to the activism of Carter’s principals working in the region (Pastor 1992, 61).