Forthcoming in Ethnicity, Race and Nationalism in the Caribbean, edited by Anton Allahar,
Lexington Press, 2004.
Nationalism, Identity and the Banking
Sector:
The English-speaking Caribbean in the Era of Financial Globalization
Introduction
At the beginning of the 21st
century, the structure of banking markets in the English speaking Caribbean
reflected a shift from the 1970s of large government-owned commercial banks and
some foreign-owned banks, to a consolidated banking market dominated by private
ownership, based primarily in Canada
and Trinidad. In this paper I examine how changes in the
ownership of banks reflects perceptions of national and regional identity in
the English speaking Caribbean, with a particular focus on Trinidad and
Jamaica. In so doing I link the physical institution of banks and the political
and economic decisions manifested in banking policy to the notions of
nationalism and identity in the 21st century English speaking
Caribbean.
Perceptions and definitions of
national identity are influenced and formed by political ideologies and
political rhetoric. Once arrived at, these ideas of national identity are
manifested in symbols such as government policies, state institutions, and
cultural events such as festivals and awards ceremonies. Just as ideas about
national identity change with time and political trends, so does the context
within which governments and political movements attempt to create symbols of
national identity. For example, it may be the case that an external environment
may change to the extent that extant notions of national identity are no longer
feasible in the new context. This is the case with the banking sector in the Caribbean.
I argue that the recent changes in the ownership structure of the banking
sector in the Caribbean has augured for a context in which banks are no longer
suitable as symbols of national identity at the individual island level.
However, rather than shift the identification with the banks as a symbol of
nationalism to one of regionalism, banks are no longer used as political
symbols at all.
Analyzing the changes in the use of
banks as symbols of national identity reveals subtle but important dimensions
of how political leaders attempt to construct concepts of identity. This is
particularly interesting in the contemporary context where the dynamics of
traditional symbols of national identity, such as banks, are as, if not more,
influenced by external forces as they are by domestic or internal factors. By
focusing on the banking sector as a microcosm and material manifestation of
political ideas, I argue that 21st century ideas of identity in the Caribbean
continue to reflect an emphasis on island-specific notions of nationhood. This
continuation of post-independence trends comes at the expense of the creation
of a true regional identity, suggesting that even as global dynamics change,
individual Caribbean states re-shape their political
rhetoric to maintain individualistic ideas of national identity.
Globalization and Banking in the Caribbean
The late 20th and the
beginning of the 21st century are overwhelmingly characterized by
the political and economic shifts and accommodations to continued
globalization. We can understand globalization in the context of this paper as
a continuing process of economic and political restructuring on a global scale
that directly and indirectly brings about political and economic realignments
on a national scale, at the same as those national-level realignments
dynamically influence change at the global level. In practice, contemporary
globalization can be understood as comprising neoliberal policy applications
and the multifaceted occurrences of multinationalization and
internationalization.
Neoliberalism as a policy framework comprises financial anti-inflation
measures, trade and capital market liberalization, and the reduction of
government intervention at the domestic level (Milner and Keohane
1996: 20). Contemporary neoliberal policy responses to globalization, in
developed and developing countries, generally comprise the deregulation of economic activity,
privatization of government enterprises, openness to foreign investment and
trade, and the rationalization of the fiscal account. Neoliberalism assumes
that markets are free and fair, and that left to the market, the economy and
society will realize the optimal outcomes of efficient resource allocation.
Neoliberalism further proposes that all economies obey certain universal laws
of economics, rather than the opposing view that economic processes are embedded
in specific social and political contexts (Girvan 2000: 70).
At the global level, neoliberalism’s advocates
argue that countries will perform those productive functions that the global
market “freely and fairly” deems they are best suited to, thus achieving global
competitiveness where their national endowments (whether of land, labour or
intellectual capital) allow them to. Norman Girvan argues, however, that
“competitiveness achieved at the cost of increasing unemployment, social
exclusion, poverty and inequality is not acceptable” (2000: 70).
Yet another challenge to neoliberalism’s
opposition is its endorsement by the global power elite. For example,
neoliberalism has been the main ideological influence behind global trade
agreements, specifically as embodied in the World Trade Organization
agreements, and including the Free Trade Area of the Americas
and European Union agreements. These international regimes have not come about
as a result of a democratic process in which all global citizens are equally
represented, and the rule-makers of these trade regimes correspond to those
countries that are globally politically and militarily dominant. The
implication is that developing countries have little say in these rules, but
appear to be much more subject to severe economic and political pressures
should they break those rules (Block 1994: 704).
Multinationalization, or
transnationalization, implies the integration of production and service
provision across national borders, often via direct foreign direct investment
abroad, under the rubric of one large corporation, whose home base is usually
in a developed country. This process of global sourcing, in its twentieth
century incarnation, began in the 1960s. Global sourcing is “the use of
multiple sources in different countries for the components of a particular
product that is assembled elsewhere” (Knox and Agnew 1998: 282). In some cases,
newly independent countries that sought to participate in the global economy
attempted to capitalize on their perceived comparative advantage of surplus
labour and primary products, and thus incorporated themselves into the global
production chain of multinational (or transnational) corporations. Other developing countries incorporated
themselves into the global production chain upon the realization of the
limitations of autonomous import
substitution industrialization strategies. As early as the mid-1950s, in Asia and Latin America, companies with the technology and capital
were invited in to broaden the range of local production to include more
consumer goods, as well as to build up local manufacture of capital and
intermediate goods that were still imported and which drained foreign reserves
(Gereffi and Evans 1995: 211).
Internationalization is akin to
multinationalization, except that it implies a more spontaneous set of actions
and activities that emerge out of the openings created by the revolution in
information technology, and the neoliberal policies that precede, facilitate
and accompany globalization. Internationalization is that set of “processes
generated by underlying shifts in transaction costs that produce observable
flows of goods, services and capital”:
Internationalization
affects the opportunities and constraints facing social and economic actors,
and therefore their policy preferences. As incentives change through
internationalization, we expect to observe changes in economic policies and in
political institutions. (Milner and Keohane 1996: 4)
Thus internationalization could be
considered the precursor to increased multinationalization, while both are the
outcomes of globalization.
Since the end of the Cold War and the concomitant sea change in the
global economy, access to new and cheaper sources of labour and raw
materials has increased with increased communication and transportation
technology. The realization of these new opportunities is made possible by
trade and economic opening on the part of those countries, many of whom have
formulated and implemented neoliberal economic policies. Together with the
changes in global politics, these new patterns of industrial organization in
the world economy imply that a nation’s development prospects “are dependent on
how it is inserted into global commodity chains” (Gereffi
1994: 225).
An evaluation of the results of these processes of globalization,
neoliberalism, multinationalization and internationalization is beyond the
scope of this paper. In most developing countries in the 21st
century, including in the Caribbean,
economic and social problems are unwieldy and increasing. The state in
developing countries has less control over both its internal and external
environment. Whether this is a direct result of globalization, or of forces and
trends related to globalization that are simultaneously producing these
phenomena, or an outcome of an entirely discrete set of dynamics coincidental
to globalization, remains the subject of debate.
In the midst of this, at the state decision-making level, there is a
broad agreement on a few general assumptions regarding any short and medium
term economic development strategy:
- The Caribbean cannot disengage from the international
economy or avoid its trading/production position in relation to the world
economy; its most viable option is to attempt to maximize its “inevitable”
position in the international economy.
- The Caribbean is dependent on foreign capital and
trade, especially in services such as tourism, for economic growth.
- Both of these
mean that the Caribbean must also play by political rules and
norms that might not be of their own choosing, were all else equal. These
political rules include:
(a) A foreign policy that at best pleases and at
worst does not offend the regional and world hegemon, the United States of
America (U.S.);
(b)
Domestic economic policies in line with those promoted
by the U.S. and by multilateral financial institutions, mainly involving fiscal
cutbacks, privatization of state enterprises, and lowering of barriers to
trade;
(c)
The practice of U.S.-style liberal democracy, or at
least the appearance of such, even where it is not compatible with traditional
political configurations, or it has been so corrupted as to be a farce.
(d)
Agreement to the implementation of policies and
programmes, usually designed and funded by the U.S.,
intended to stem the supply and passage of drugs illegal in the U.S.
Even where these policies and programmes breach international law, such as the
jurisdiction of territorial waters, or go against local traditions, such as the
growing of non-cocaine-intended coca, the pressure to accept them is enormous.
This leaves Caribbean
countries with little room to maneuver. It would appear that their best option,
at this point, is to optimize their options within these strictures, while
attempting to maintain domestic political and social consensus, as well as some
measure of political control at the domestic level. This is, indeed, a
formidable challenge, akin to being painted in the proverbial corner.
Given the common
trend in policy across a large number of developing countries, there are good
reasons to think that international systemic pressures are at work and that the
developing countries’ growing integration with the world economy has
constrained government choices with respect to international financial policy.
(Haggard and Maxfield 1996: 210)
As will be clear from the above
understanding of globalization, the process of globalization creates openings
for shifts in political dynamics, which may also lead to struggles for power
and control in a new environment. The question then arises with regard to the
financial sector: Does the globalization of financial services also lead to
realignments or shifts in the political status
quo ante? It is safe to say that where power connotes privilege and
control, no holder of power is likely to want to give it up, or share it, and
will therefore attempt to maintain its position (Coleman 1996: 19). This paper
explores how, in the Caribbean, the changing power
dynamics in the financial sector have manifested themselves in relation to
nationalism, regionalism and identity.
The Political Economy of the Financial Sector: Global Considerations
There is a process of consolidation
underway in the banking industry throughout the world. The multinationalization
of retail banking in the late 20th century is a global phenomenon
(IMF 2000: 152). The internationalization of financial services must be
understood as an interplay of the domestic situation within the country—what
can be called “pull factors”—and a number of “push” factors on the part of the
banks themselves. Since the 1990s, these two sets of factors have created a
sort of inevitability as the global banking industry follows certain trends and
patterns. Starting in the early 1990s, throughout the world, most national
regulations regarding banks had been significantly liberalized. With increasing
levels of deregulation, domestic banks lose their monopoly position over retail
banking activities as barriers to entry fall (Pomerleano
and Vojta 2001). At the same time, individuals’
financial behaviour has grown more varied, complex and sophisticated, with a
greater demand for more, and more efficient, financial products and services.
Along with this must be considered the rapid developments in technology that
have been developed and applied to the financial industry, just in the decade
of the 1990s, many entailing significant front-end investment requirements
(Smith and Walter 1997: 102). This global scenario is entirely relevant to the
consideration of the Caribbean financial sector in the
21st century.
In sum, there
are five major aspects of the multinationalization of retail banking:
- The domestic political economy vis-à-vis the banking
sector and entry barriers to foreign banks (“pull factors”)
- Motivation of banks to expand beyond their home
country (push factor)[1]
- Global trends towards deregulation of the banking
sector (push factor)
- Global trends towards consolidation in the banking
industry (push factor)
- Increased consumer demand for more and more
sophisticated financial services at the same time as such services are for
the most part delivered via new and expensive technology, investments
which can be offset by economies of scale (pull factor)
There is synergy among many of
these five factors. The demand for new and expensive technology offset by
economies of scale promotes greater consolidation. Similarly, as countries
follow the “trend” of deregulation, foreign banks are presented with
opportunities for expansion that did not previously exist. For example, in an
analysis of the Spanish banks in Latin America, Guillén and Tschoegl (1999)
conclude that the Spanish expansion resulted from a saturation of the Spanish
market, and a lack of market opportunity in Europe and Asia,
at the same time as Latin American banking markets were being deregulated and
liberalized in the early 1990s. The Spanish banks, having recently experienced
radical market liberalization themselves, sought to use their market know-how
and implement new information and telecommunications technologies in culturally
and linguistically comfortable environments.
Thus, the changes in the
composition of the banking sector in the Caribbean are
representative of a broader global trend. Indeed, most policy changes with
regard to the financial sector in the Caribbean have
been common to other developing countries, era by era, trend by trend. Most
developing countries had enacted some sort of legislation during the 1960s and
1970s that either barred or restricted foreign banks from entering their
countries. As well, some developing countries undertook the nationalization of
foreign banks that had been present in the region for decades. In many
sub-Saharan African countries in the 1960s the banking sectors were largely
controlled by private foreign banks that remained after independence. The
foreign banks’ risk-averse lending objectives, and the absence of a priority on
their part towards local entrepreneurs, often led to nationalization of the
foreign banks. By the 1980s most of these banks were insolvent, and by the
1990s they were re-privatized and re-sold to foreign owners once again (Murinde 2001).
In Colombia,
prior to 1967, foreign investment was not restricted as it fit into the general
outward-oriented development model. In 1967, however, the state reassigned
itself as the director of investment and production, and no new foreign
investment, including in the banking sector, was approved. In 1970, after Colombia
had joined the Andean Pact, further restrictions were placed on investment in
the financial sector, as the Andean Pact reserved the financial sector only for
domestic investors, or investors from member countries (Barajas et al. 2000).[2]
In 1970s in Chile
the banking system was nationalized by the Allende
administration with the direct aim of gaining control of the commanding heights
of the Chilean economy. The ostensible aim was to cut off control of the
resource allocation mechanism from the business and middle class groups that
had held it for the previous 50 years (Bosworth et al. 1994: 31). Shortly after
Allende was overthrown, the economic reforms included
re-privatization of banks. In December 1974 Chile
abandoned the Andean Pact so as to allow foreign banks to open subsidiaries and
branches and to allow direct foreign investment in commercial banks (Bosworth
et al. 1994: 155).
Today, even in India,
where banking institutions and the social content of lending are still
considered legitimate instruments of social and economic change, the rules
governing the entry of foreign banks changed significantly in the 1990s. There
continue to be restrictions on the percentage of equity foreign entities can
own in domestic banks, but by 2002 there were 28 banks operating in India,
with another 20 maintaining representative offices (Arun
and Turner 2002).
What is different about the Caribbean
is the way in which domestic political dynamics, as created by history and
specific interpretations of history, accommodate these global trends.
Throughout the developing world, and the developed world too, the
internationalization of the financial sector under globalization has taken
place. But the paths that individual countries have taken to arrive at their
distinct national consequences depend on the structure of the national
financial system. As John Zysman’s seminal study on
the political economy of financial systems argues, domestic issues are worth
focusing on exclusively, “not because the dramatic changes in international
monetary and banking systems are unimportant, but because one can isolate the
dominant domestic structural elements that determine the domestic ramifications
of an international economic development” (1983: 56).
Examining the Caribbean
financial sector in the era of financial globalization is not only worthwhile
as an academic exercise. In the context of developing countries’ experiences in
the contemporary global financial polity, the English speaking Caribbean
is virtually unique in being one of the only set of countries that has emerged
in the 21st century with strong indigenous banking institutions.
Indeed, the Caribbean is one of the few developing
regions with “national champions”.[3]
This alone is worth exploring as a complete anomaly in the literature and
experience of the globalization of the financial sector.
Economic Nationalism and the Banking Sector
The study of banks and banking is
usually assumed to be the purview of economists; however, banks are important
symbols of national identity, and are fulcrums for political and economic
power. In economic theory, banks are considered to be key intermediaries by
which money is created, distributed, and stored (Mizruchi
and Brewster 1994), but banks are not simply mechanistic economic institutions
that operate in financial market vacuums. Banks, and who controls them, are
potential sources and explanations of power in a society. Banks are also key
symbols in economic nationalism. It is well established that domestic political
influence and private financiers influence financial sector reform.[4]
Thus political power is an essential concept for the study of the politics of
financial services (Coleman 1996).
As a historical phenomenon,
nationalism constantly changes (Wright 1974).
Economic nationalism in the twentieth century has its own dynamics,
quite different from those of nineteenth century mercantilism. Modern economic
nationalism can be dated to the post-World War II era, as the wave of
independence and national autonomy spread throughout the developing world. As Samir Amin (1987) puts it,
achieving political independence augured for a national bourgeois project to
bring certain processes under control through the state and by the hegemonic
national bourgeois class. These processes included control over natural
resources, markets, and “financial circuits thus enabling the centralization of
surplus and the orientation of its productive use.” Thus control over the
banking sector is germane to economic nationalism.
More specifically, as part of a
political ideology, economic nationalism optimistically promises a better
material future for a nation’s citizens.
As a driving
force, economic nationalism has two primary objectives. First, it seeks an
amorphous goal of achieving as much economic self-sufficiency for a nation as
possible. The second goal relates to the first and encompasses the attempts of
developing states to pattern their economies after those of recognized world
powers. Both objectives imply that a nation can achieve and secure the
well-being of the individual citizen by controlling its own economic resources.
Economic nationalists believe that a nation’s greatness depends upon its
economic strength. They also maintain that political independence hinges upon
economic power. Thus the fight for freedom is translated into a fight against
outside economic penetration. (Wright 1974: 7)
This definition of economic
nationalism falls squarely within the parameters of the Caribbean
historical experience.
The role of the banking
sector—insofar as it channels savings to credits and participates in the system
of payments—in economic development has always been preeminent, regardless of
the ideological basis of the economic development strategy, or the composition
of the productive sector. This is because the banking system is the main
arbiter of channeling savings to credit for investment, and because it controls
the system of payments. Even private banks may be vulnerable to being leaned on
by governments to direct and manage the flows of capital within their
countries: “they can be influenced quietly and privately to favour certain
industries, firms, projects, or regions” (Beim and Calomiris 2001: 256). Therefore the banking sector is
central to ongoing political debates involving governments, financial and
industrial elites, developmental ideologies, and the role of market forces.
Accordingly, banks are important institutions for economic nationalists.
Firstly, financial institutions are
central to economic development, especially in market economies, which most Caribbean
countries ostensibly are, or aim to become. Banks are at the center of economic
and financial activity, and are distinct from other economic or financial
institutions as primary providers of payments services and as a fulcrum for
monetary policy implementation. Financial institutions and markets rely on the
payment system to mobilize, allocate and transform domestic and international
savings into productive investments. A country’s payment system is essential to
the development of money and capital markets and the implementation of monetary
policy. Retail banks play a number of functions in a market economy, primarily
as conduits for information, instruments for the payment of goods and services,
and repositories for savings and investment.[5]
The retail banking sector is also important as a growth sector in and of
itself: as economies become more market-driven, and individuals become more
aware of their choices as consumers, the sector is an increasingly important
provider of goods and services whose profit-making potential expands
exponentially with the liberalization of an economy.
Second, bank fragility is of critical
concern to policy makers because of the negative externalities associated with
bank failures, and the contagion and domino effects that bank failure can have
on other banks, and on the economy. Public policy is also especially concerned
with banks because of the public goods that banks provide vis-à-vis payments
services and savings mobilization; virtually no government will permit
widespread bank failures. Decisions regarding the payment system are policy
matters, and not merely a technological or technical project. Such public
involvement has political as well as economic determinants (Lindgren et al
1996: 6).
Third, economic nationalists
consider that the banking system is an inherent part of sovereignty. In an era
of financial globalization, there may be fears that domestic groups will lose
access to financial services, as well as concerns that the country could lose
control over the course of development if the domestic banking system is taken
over by non-nationally owned banks (Pomerleano and Vojta 2001: 3). In this vein, Makler
and Ness (2002) have explored how changes in financial
intermediation, particularly the ownership of banks by non-nationals, challenge
sovereignty in developing countries. They argue that the globalization of
financial institutions and markets combine with domestic financial structure to
powerfully challenge national sovereignty by weakening the state’s ability to
make and enforce domestic policies, and ultimately eroding a country’s
capability to project and maintain power.
Finally, at the micro level,
individual banks operate based on access to private, usually quite sensitive
information from debtors, and in accordance or response to the broader
investment and political climate in which they are situated. The control and
management of that type of information is critical, especially where members of
a standing government are themselves entrepreneurs or debtors in some way to
financial institutions. The identification of debtors in the aftermath of the
Jamaican financial crisis of the 1990s was a contentious issue for exactly this
reason. The Minister of Finance argued that while public money had bailed out
the banks, the identification of the benefactors of taxpayers’ dollars would
risk serious social and political cleavages. This makes for an interesting
dynamic where ownership changes from nationals to non-nationals, with regard to
pre-existing and sometimes long-standing bank-client (whether government or
private individual) relationships that were not entirely based on rational
economic decision making.
Banks, Finance and Identity in the Caribbean
Money is power, simply put.
Money—how much of it there is and how it is allocated—is fundamental to a
country’s political, economic and social relations. Money may not be the
entirety of an economy and a society, but it affects most of what happens in
one way or another (Hoffman 2001: 20). Money is also an important symbol of
identity. Nowhere is this more evident than in newly independent countries, for
whom an “own” currency, bearing a nationally relevant name and/or images of
national icons was among the first order of business, along with a national
anthem and a flag. After the failure of the West Indies Federation,
and subsequently individual independence in the 1960s, a number of steps were
taken to establish a national identity. One of these steps involved the
creation of a national currency for each island, abandoning the West Indian
dollar that had acted as a regional currency since 1951. For example, in Jamaica
the front of each bank note bears the portrait of either a Jamaican national
hero or a former Prime Minister, while local scenes and popular landmarks
appear on the back. In sub-Saharan Africa, the names of
the currencies range from the Zambian kwacha and the Angolan kwanza, to the Botswana
pula and the Ghanaian cedi, all reflecting the names of traditional,
pre-colonial means of exchange.
The creation and existence of a
Central Bank is also an important symbol of identity and status as a sovereign
state, beyond its practical function as an institution in the national monetary
and financial system. Central banks were established as real symbols of
nationhood, and a major aspect of the effort to “shed the yoke of colonialism”
(Danns 1996: 5). Jamaica’s
creation of its own Central Bank in 1960 was one of the first signs that Jamaica
was contemplating withdrawal from the West Indies Federation
(Brown 1989: 164). Ironically, in the 21st century context of Caribbean
politics, where the idea of a monetary union is held as the ultimate symbol of
regional integration, those steps taken in the early 1960s meant the demise of
what was the first true regional financial institution (Danns
1996: 3).
Beyond the Central Bank, retail and
commercial banks are also used as symbols of national pride and identity. In
the Caribbean, commercial banks have been used as
symbols of national identity and as political focal points for decades. The
banking sector as a symbol of national identity has many different and
sometimes contradictory aspects, however. The ownership of the bank may or may
not affect where the average retail customer—the working person with a checking
and a savings account, for example—takes his business. In countries where the
national banks have been weak, retail customers tend to prefer to take their
business to a foreign bank, with the expectation that they are more stable and
trustworthy. This was the case in Argentina,
where in 1995 deposits moved from domestic to foreign institutions in the wake
of the Mexico
“Tequila Crisis”. After decades of government intervention in private deposits,
the general idea was that foreign banks would not be subject to the
vicissitudes of Argentine government bank policy. Nevertheless, banks are used
as symbols of identity when the conditions surrounding the banks are perceived
as favourable. For example, in Mexico
after the near complete takeover of the domestic banking sector by foreign
banks, there was one remaining Mexican-owned bank, Banorte.
Banorte, based on consumer and market surveys,
carefully manipulated its ownership status in its public relations and
advertisements. In Argentina,
the one remaining Argentine-owned bank, Banco Galicia
capitalized on its foreign-sounding name when depositors were transferring
their deposits from local institutions. However, when the financial crisis
broke in 2001, and public resentment was directed towards the foreign banks,
Banco Galicia
changed its public relations strategy to emphasize its “Argentine-ness”. While
banks may not capture the rousing sentiments of a national sports team, or even
a strong foreign policy position such as the Jamaican government’s strong
opposition to the U.S.’s
proposed Ship Rider Agreement in 1997, there is a strong basis for arguing that
the ownership of a bank is relevant to a sense of national identity and
national pride. There are two distinct periods in recent Caribbean
history that further support this argument.
In Jamaica
in the 1970s, during the highly nationalist administration of the People’s
National Party, the Worker’s Savings and Loan Bank was founded in 1973.
The WSLB was born
during the 1970s, a time when the ruling government moved the public sector in
the direction of taking over the “commanding heights of the economy”. Greater
local financing of the powerful banking sector was the objective of this drive
as the then banking sector was not believed to be doing enough to support and
facilitate local development, especially in new areas of growth.[6]
The Jamaican Government also
nationalized Barclays in 1977, and changed its name to the National Commercial
Bank (NCB). NCB had started out as the Colonial Bank of London
and began operating in Kingston, Jamaica
in 1837. In 1925 the 11 branches of the Colonial Bank were acquired by Barclays
Bank of London. In 1975, Barclays
Bank transferred its Jamaican operation to a wholly owned subsidiary, Barclays
Bank of Jamaica Limited. The NCB takeover was in many ways the epitome of
nationalism and nationalization.[7]
The Black Power movement in Trinidad,
in expressing its frustrations with the failure of the promises of
independence, focused much of its energy on the Canadian commercial banks that
dominated the banking system. For these political activists, the banking sector
provided a clear example of imperial domination and control in Trinidad.
It may also be argued that the storied preference of the banks for
“fair-skinned” employees was a key factor in the choice of the banks as a Black
Power target. Deryck Brown (1989) argues that it was
the events of 1970 that precipitated what became the “localization” of the
foreign banks in Trinidad and Tobago. In responding to the sentiments expressed
by the Black Power movement, the government’s agenda sought to increase
national participation in “important sectors of the economy” (181). What
followed was a decades-long process of legislation geared towards forcing the
foreign banks to issue local share offers. This process culminated in a
near-complete “indigenization” of the Trinidadian banking sector by the
beginning of the 21st century, and, perhaps surprising from the
viewpoint of the early 1970s, Trinidadian bank expansion throughout the English
speaking Caribbean.
The second clear episode where we
can identify images and issues of national identity in the banking sector was
in Jamaica in
the early 1990s. As a result of the privatization and liberalization policies
carried out, a number of nationally owned private banks entered the market in
the early 1990s. By 1994 there were many “indigenous” private financial institutions
of many different types, including a number of retail banks. It was widely
noted, at the time, that “the bulk of government assets appear to have gone to
young black professionals or small to medium entrepreneurs. Workers Bank was
sold, not to interest in the 21 families,[8]
but to a relatively inexperienced group of black entrepreneurs.”[9]
Again, one might be able to see hints of the resentment against the colonial
and early post-Independence days’ preference for light-skinned bank workers
resurfacing here.
It can be argued that this
comprised the PNP’s larger effort to create a black
entrepreneurial class and black economic elite. At the time, the new
“indigenous” banks were held up by the government and the media as
nationalistic examples of Jamaicanness, and often too
of black entrepreneurship—images that were key to the implicit identity of the
governing party and its political rhetoric, particularly during the 1993
election in which P.J. Patterson is widely held to have played the “race card”.
These banks invested widely in real estate, tourism, and agriculture. While
these extra-banking forays were retrospectively seen as a major cause of the
later fallout, these investments were undertaken “in the mood of the 1980s and
the early 1990s, when there was official government policy support for the
expansion of the domestic financial sector into the productive sector.”[10]
An in-depth study of these
“non-economic” factors of race and identity behind the Jamaican financial
sector debacle has yet to be done. There are, however, some widely held
perceptions, including on the part of the PNP itself, as to what transpired:
Dr. [Omar] Davies
(PNP Member of Parliament and Jamaican Minister of Finance) in a bold speech in
the pre-election period, admitted to two errors. One, that he indulged in some
amount of social engineering by encouraging indigenous participation in the
ownership and control of major banking institutions. Two, that in his
zealousness to achieve a sociological (as opposed to an economic) objective, he
stepped over the line in giving "blys" (I
take that to mean unmerited favours) to individuals who would be proved by
subsequent developments to be either unworthy of such considerations or
incapable of making good on them.
The admission is
innocuous enough in that it points to a fault or weakness in the minister that
almost any progressive or nationalistic-minded Jamaican would forgive.[11]
The indigenous bankers that headed
these banks were, as it is phrased in Jamaica,
“visibly black”. They were feted in the media, by the political elite, and by
the wider community. The cases of Century National Bank and of the Worker’s
Bank epitomize this phenomenon, though virtually all of the “indigenous”
bankers of the early 1990s fit this general trajectory. The charismatic head of
Century started out as a teller at the Bank of Nova Scotia (BNS) in the
mid-1960s, rising to the position of Senior Assistant Manager of the BNS head
office. He was later recruited to run the Girod Bank
in Jamaica.[12]
He eventually gained a controlling interest in the bank, and it was renamed the
Century National Bank.
The government divested the
Worker’s Bank in the early 1990s. Five financial groups, three of whose roots
were inarguably in some of Jamaica’s
leading entrepreneurial (and fairer-skinned) families, bid to take control of
the bank. The winning bid was a surprise to many. The new CEO revolutionized
the banking industry, introducing new banking products and services, investing
beyond the banking sector, establishing scholarships, and winning an award for
business personality of the year in 1991. This CEO was seen as “one of the
new-breed Jamaican businessmen aggressive with against-the-odds confidence… not
so long ago, he was, by his own admission, just another ordinary Jamaican with
a big dream.”[13] Other
“stars” at Worker’s Bank were lionized in the media:
Cooly (sic)
confident, [this banker] is unruffled by the late hours and heavy demands of
his job. After all, he is only digging his teeth into what he does, and likes
best: making money. With a business savvy that has earned him the reputation of
a hard-nose financial dealer, [this banker] is himself the product of a
competitive, result oriented corporate culture which has already spawned a host
of young, rising stars in Jamaica's
financial industry.[14]
This type of press was typical of
the coverage given these high profile bankers.
The consequences of this “experiment” were disastrous
for the banking system, the economy, and the individuals involved. A summary of
the condition of the banks that were taken over by FINSAC, including the
Worker’s Bank, found a litany of woes, including unreliable financial
statements, inaccurate Bank of Jamaica reporting, non-existent investments
recorded on bank accounts, loans diverted to subsidiary companies to avoid
reporting as past due, and misstating financial statements and inflating
balances, among many, many other findings (FINSAC 1999). Except for a very
brief prison stay for one banker, none have yet been prosecuted, but they are
all either living outside of Jamaica, or in much humbler
circumstances just a decade after being held up as splendid models of
entrepreneurship, success and possibility. For some, too, it is lamentable that
“[t]he country has returned to the days when Jamaicans of a darker hue
would be hard-pressed to recall names and count off on one hand, people in
“big” business who look like them. There is an unintended but inestimable cost
to all of this.”[15]
Interestingly, and adding further
weight to the argument that banks reflect perceptions of national identity, is
the presence of two Indian banks, in the two CARICOM countries that have
significant Indian populations. The Bank of Baroda operates in Guyana
and the Intercommercial Bank operates in Trinidad
and Tobago. The role and operations of these
banks, and their relationship to Indian identity in Guyana
and Trinidad merits further research. Their presence,
however, points to some of the underlying “fault lines” of a prospective
Caribbean regional identity, with regard to the question of the possibility of
creating a Caribbean identity where “Indians in the Caribbean have had a
somewhat ambivalent relationship with the other peoples of the region and to
proposals for its political unification” (Ryan 1999: 151).
Beyond the use of currency and
financial institutions as political symbols of national identity, governments
are concerned with bank ownership for less direct reasons of power and control.
Banks and other financial services firms possess economic power in market economies
through their control over the allocation of credit, the behaviour of financial
markets, and as well through their relationships with the productive sector and
their customer base. This economic power provides these firms with a
considerable potential to shape what become matters for political consideration
and to influence the outcomes of the public policy process. Governments,
therefore, have multiple interests in maintaining, at best, control over, and,
at worst, a mutually beneficial relationship with, those banks operating in
their domestic system. At the same time, financial services firms seek to
protect and further their interests through obtaining special access to
political leaders, either through personal contacts, or via institutional government
relations divisions that monitor the policy-making process (Coleman 1996).
The history of banking in the Caribbean
explicates this argument. During the nineteenth century, up until independence
in the 1960s, the banking sector was primarily geared towards financing and
facilitating trading relations between the colony and the metropole. There was
virtually no investment in production or consumer credit. This de facto established the identity of the
then-Caribbean colonies as exporters of primary products and consumers of
manufactured goods. The main banks present in the region were the British
Barclays, that had grown out of the original Colonial Bank that was established
in the 1820s and 1830s throughout the region, and three Canadian banks, Bank of
Nova Scotia (BNS), the Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce (CIBC), and the Royal
Bank of Canada.
Canadian banks began establishing themselves in the Caribbean
in 1910 and by World War I “could be described as major financial institutions
in the Caribbean” (Baum 1974: 21).
In the decade after independence,
the foreign-owned banks began to be conceptualized as a chief target of rising
economic nationalism. Advocates of the economic nationalism of the 1960s
considered foreign ownership of strategic sectors a barrier to economic
development, and ultimately, to political independence. Public ownership and
control of key economic sectors became a primary goal.
Decisions about the banking sector
would have been made in the context of dependency theory, which had become
something of the reigning economic orthodoxy in many developing countries in
the 1970s. Dependency theory broadly prescribed economic policies that were
intended to insulate the domestic economy from international shocks.
As Clive Thomas stated in 1966:
[…W]e are
satellite economies integrated to each other and to the U.K. and U.S.A. by a
pervasive system of branches of financial institutions with Head Offices in
these metropolitan countries. These institutions are neither exclusively
concerned with developments within our economy or with promoting the sort of
regional integration we may desire. Their exclusive interest is to make profits
on all their operations, no matter
where they may be located. Ultimately the only effective reform is the development
of indigenous institutions and the imposition of controls on the movement of
all funds outside the region.
Through the 1970s and 1980s, the
larger CARICOM countries moved from branch banking operations owned and run by
British and Canadian banks, to full or part-nationalization by governments.
Localisation
occurred first in Jamaica
and almost immediately afterward in Trinidad and
Tobago, following a wave of structuralist economic thought of the 1960s and 1970s. Some
economists, among them [George] Beckford, explicitly
recommended the nationalization of commercial banks, and by the mid-1970s most
banks in both Jamaica
and Trinidad and Tobago
were either locally or government owned. (Williams 1996: 68)
The newly independent countries
felt it necessary to have banks that would be more responsive to the needs of
the local economy and to nationally determined developmental objectives. The
thinking was that the “banking arrangements of the pre-independence era did not
favour economic and social progress in the colonies… . The mechanics of the
[colonial] banking system, as economist Clive Thomas wrote, favoured the
transfer of resources to overseas, and not to the host country,” (July 1995:
91). Commercial banks were seen to hold “the key to resource allocation and had
the collective institutional capacity to determine lasting outcomes in the [Caribbean]
economies,” (Danns 1996: 21).
By 1974 the
situation was such that a Canadian analyst wrote:
For a number of reasons,
both rational and irrational, there is a Commonwealth Caribbean sense of being
exploited, and an answer is found for many in what must be described as black
nationalism. Not infrequently, Canadian banks as holders of money find
themselves the object of blame. After all, so the argument might run, the banks
hold the money; if the banks used their deposits in the interests of the
people, then the people would prosper. (Baum 1974: 6)
According
to Baum, growing nationalism “nudged” the Canadian banks to offer stock, and in
some cases, control to nationals of the islands in which they operated. Where
the “nudging” was not heeded, a government might have intervened, expropriated
and re-formed a locally owned bank, as happened with the Bank of Montreal in Trinidad.
It was actions such as these that further “nudged” Canadian banks to “localize”
ownership and, ostensibly, control (26).
Throughout the Caribbean
there were moves towards ownership and localization in one form or another. Danns (1996) chronicles the various actions taken in Guyana,
Trinidad, Jamaica,
and Barbados.
Where Caribbean governments did not nationalize foreign
banks, regulations were designed so that loan requests were directed to sectors
that had been targeted based on overall development goals (July 1995: 92). Many
of these regulations brought about conditions of financial repression, where
government intervention to set interest rates and direct the flow of credit,
combined with price inflation, was detrimental to the deposit base for domestic
bank lending (McKinnon 1973).[16]
These trends were not limited to
the Caribbean. As but one example, in Colombia,
prior to 1967, foreign investment was not restricted as it fit into the general
outward-oriented development model. Foreign investment in the financial system
dated to 1912, and the first financial legislation of 1923 did not restrict
foreign banks. In 1967 a new foreign exchange and trade regime was adopted,
based on strict foreign exchange controls. The state reassigned itself as the
director of investment and production, and no new foreign investment, including
in the banking sector, was approved, though it was not explicitly restricted by
law. After 1970, the Andean Pact (to which Colombia
was signatory) reserved the financial sector only for domestic investors, or
investors from member countries.[17]
Branches of foreign banks had to convert themselves into domestic firms. No new
direct foreign investment in the financial system was allowed. In the early
1990s the laws were changed, the system became fully open, and foreign banks entered
Colombia once
again (Barajas et al 2000).
In sub-Saharan Africa,
where the history of the financial sector was more similar to the Caribbean
than that of Latin America, there was also a similar
pattern of events in the banking sector. In African countries in the 1960s the
banking sectors were largely controlled by private foreign banks that remained
after independence. Their risk-averse lending objectives and the absence of a
priority on their part towards local entrepreneurs often led to nationalization
of the now-foreign banks. By the 1980s most of these banks were insolvent, and
by the 1990s they were re-privatized and re-sold to foreign owners once again (Murinde 2001).
These policies that aimed to
fulfill the nationalist aspirations of newly independent countries, such as
those in the Caribbean, were in many ways attempts to
replicate of similar processes and policies underway in the developed world.
Particularly with regard to the financial sector, most developed countries in
the post-WWII era placed stringent controls on cross-border capital movements
and on the ownership of domestic financial institutions. The liberalized
trading relations envisioned by the United
States and the United
Kingdom were limited to commodities, and to
an extent, services. The financial sector, however, was to remain under the
control of national governments. The main intellectual framers of the post-WWII
economic order “concluded that a liberal international financial order would
undermine the new state role emerging at the domestic level” (Coleman 1996).
The irony of the economic
nationalism of the 1960s and 1970s, in many developing countries, is that it
set out, as a populist measure, to give control of the country’s economic
resources to the “people”. The result, in many cases, however, was a
consolidation of economic power in the bourgeois political elite and their
private sector elite constituents. As an economic strategy it failed.
Structural Adjustment and Changing Dynamics of Banks and Identity
Beginning in the late 1970s, there
was the realization (whether conscious or forced) that nationalist economic
plans would not produce the expected growth and development, in the context of
the changing international economy. In the 1980s, “structural adjustment” policies
were implemented in most Caribbean countries, with their
general prescriptions of diminishing state regulation, ownership and control
over the economy. Structural adjustment resulted in the “freeing up of the
region’s financial sector from strangling exchange and other controls and
regulations,” (Danns 1996: 4).
Policy makers were forced
to accept the deficiencies of the structuralist
approach… indeed it is ironic that those Caribbean countries which were most
wedded to the structuralist approaches have abandoned
those views and now adhere to the more monetarist prescriptions prescribed by
the international financial institutions. (Williams 1996: 231)
Whether due to the divestment of
government holdings of publicly-owned banks, gradual divestment via public
share offers of foreign banks over many decades, or new startups by Caribbean
nationals, the ownership structure in the banking sector shifted to nearly
complete private ownership, both national and foreign.
After a decade of what could be
considered “settling into” the new realities of private ownership, an open
market economy, and further openness to the international economy, by the
beginning of the 21st century the number of banks owned by Caribbean
nationals was lower in 2003 than it was at the beginning of the 1990s. This is
especially so because of the fallout in Jamaica
in the mid-1990s, and the closure or takeover of virtually all the ‘indigenous’
banks there. After a brief heyday in the early 1990s of Jamaican-owned
commercial and merchant banks, that for a short time promised to become
regional financial giants, the banking sector in the Caribbean
has consolidated. The Caribbean-owned banks that remain, in large part,
particularly those in Trinidad and Tobago,
are strong and are successfully expanding throughout the Caribbean
(Bissember 2003).
One of the casualties of the 1990s
was the Jamaican banking sector. In part due to internal mismanagement and poor
investment decisions, and in part due to an exceptionally harsh macroeconomic
policy environment, virtually all of the banks failed in the midst of a
financial sector crisis that began in 1996. Jamaica’s
financial sector crisis is proportionally one of the costliest in the world,
costing over ten times that of the Mexican “Tequila Crisis” of 1994-5, in terms
of the amount the government had to put out to prevent widespread bank closures
and stabilize the banking system.
One of the principal outcomes of
the Jamaican financial crisis has been a remapping of the ownership of Jamaican
retail banks. Many of the failed banks were taken over by the government,
through its Financial Sector Adjustment Company (Finsac).
Most of the smaller ones’ assets were merged and sold together to the
Trinidadian RBTT Financial Holdings. At present in Jamaica,
then, there are now four principal retail banks. Bank of Nova Scotia, a
majority Canadian-owned bank, First Caribbean International Bank, formerly
Canadian Imperial Bank of Commerce,[18]
also majority-Canadian owned, the National Commercial Bank which was sold by
the Jamaican government to a Canadian company, AIC,[19]
and RBTT. There is no nationally owned retail bank in Jamaica
today. Concomitantly, banks are no longer used as symbols of identity, at least
not in the political dialectic. The banks themselves, however, continue to play
the identity card.
The case of the National Commercial
Bank is very interesting in this regard.
In 1986 and 1991 two public share offerings gradually sold shares to the
public, with the government eventually giving over controlling interest in the
bank to the shareholders of the Jamaica Mutual Life Assurance Society and
Jamaica National Building Society. In the early 1990s, in keeping with the
nationalist fervour of the financial sector, NCB
considered itself “bankers to the nation” or the “nation’s bank”. Internally,
the bank thrived on idealistic notions and plans to “build Jamaica”.
The bank ventured into investments in tourism and agriculture. In 1993 NCB
acquired another large bank, before going into severe fiscal problems that
nearly forced its closure; it was taken over by the Financial Sector Adjustment
Corporation (Finsac) until its sale in 2002.
While Jamaica’s
nationally owned banking sector melted down in the 1990s, Trinidad
and Tobago’s stabilized and strengthened. Trinidad
and Tobago was one of the more “aggressive”
countries in the Caribbean to nationalize its banking
sector in the 1970s, and it did not suffer the fallout of the Guyanese or the
Jamaicans. This itself warrants further indepth
research, as an inquiry into the nature of Caribbean
entrepreneurship. By 1994 five of the six retail banks in Trinidad
and Tobago were fully or majority owned by
nationals (Danns 1996, 21). For example, the Republic
Bank in Trinidad and Tobago
grew out of Barclays’ gradual divestment and sale of shares to government and
private interests. Similarly, the Royal Bank of Trinidad
and Tobago (RBTT) was created from the
assets of the former Royal Bank of Canada.
The Trinidadian influence in Jamaica,
as one of only four major banks in the country, is replicated throughout the Caribbean
region. Today it is the Trinidadian banks that are the dominant regional
players. Republic Bank in 2000 acquired majority shares of Grenada’s
National Commercial Bank, and Guyana’s
National Bank of Industry and Commerce. RBTT by 2001 had branches throughout
the English speaking Caribbean, and even in Suriname,
and the Netherlands Antilles.[20]
The other dominant force in the Caribbean banking sector
is Canada. The
Canadian banks are Barclays merged with CIBC in 2002 to create the First
Caribbean bank. With their combined operations, First Caribbean operates in
virtually every CARICOM member state. The Canadian Bank of Nova
Scotia has branches in ten CARICOM member
states.
There are still a few, albeit
small, private and public “indigenous” banks in the Caribbean,
but there is a general agreement that they will soon give way to the inevitable
consolidation already in process. Despite this reality, regionalization does
not appear to have wholeheartedly been accepted. Certainly the political
rhetoric at the popular level does not reflect this. For example, in the case
of Dominica,
according to the head of Republic Bank, one of the Trinidadian banks that is
expanding throughout the Caribbean, and thereby stands
to gain from any bank privatizations:
There is really no
good reason why the government should still be holding on to [the National
Commercial Bank of Dominica].
But it sees the bank as being a partner, with the state, in effecting
government policy. The governments feel comfortable dealing with a local bank.[21]
It would appear that these
nationally owned banks, however small, are perceived to represent one of the
last holds these governments have over their countries.
Regional Integration and the Creation of a Caribbean Identity
Beyond structural adjustment,
economic liberalization, and a reduced role for the government in
developmental-type activities and enterprises, one of the main issues for the Caribbean
in a globalized world polity is regional integration. The Caribbean integration
movement has gone from CARICOM’s 1973 objectives of
closer political, economic and social union among the former West Indies
Federation members, to a “wider and deeper” Association of Caribbean States
that include all the countries “whose shores are washed by the Caribbean Sea”.
Ostensibly responding to the West Indian Commission’s admonition to “integrate
or die”, CARICOM members meet more and more often, and continue to sign
agreements for the creation of regional institutions. Central to the success of
CARICOM, however, is the creation of a regional identity that goes beyond Heads
of Government summits.
Integration theory has long held that regional
integration is successful when ordinary citizens come to identify themselves as
part of that regional entity that the integration effort aims at. Ian Boxill has convincingly argued that successful regional
integration must be guided by an ideology that promotes regionalism. That
ideology can “only be said to exist if a common perception of the region or a
regional identity” is present (1993, 29). Boxill
concluded that the Caribbean regional integration movement is weak precisely
because “it is not based upon nor is it guided by an ideology of regionalism”
(109). In my own previous work on Caribbean integration,[22] I
have found that the processes of integration and development of a regional
identity tended to occur in sectors or programmes where CARICOM governments had
relatively little intention of this as an objective. The Caribbean
banking sector would appear to be yet another example of this phenomenon.
Terrence Farrell noted back in 1993, specifically referring to the banking
sector, this very fact:
It is not the case
that economic integration is being driven by the CARICOM political process.
Rather it is being driven by a Caribbean private sector
which has moved out front of their governments in achieving Caribbean
economic integration at the level where it really matters. The end result of
this process is likely to be a financial sector characterized by larger,
stronger institutions, with a regional presence and a hemispheric reach.
In the Caribbean,
many (if not the majority of) ordinary citizens are aware of the presence and
activities of banks. Banks have been used as symbols of national identity
throughout our post-Independence history. We have today, without any deliberate
intention or effort of CARICOM or of individual Caribbean
governments, an already regional, and “regionalizing” institution, that could
serve as a symbol of a regional identity, just as it has served as a symbol of
national identity at different times over the past decades.
Relative to the rest of the
developing world, the Caribbean banking sector is one of the few in which there
are remaining “indigenous” banks that are strong, and have the potential to
become stronger. In the political rhetoric of symbols of national identity, the
Caribbean banks ought to be a cause for celebration and
pride. They were important symbols of independence and autonomy throughout the Caribbean
in the 1970s. In Jamaica
at the beginning of the 1990s they were potent symbols of black nationalist
identity. Yet the emphasis on banks and the financial sector as symbols of
development and of a regional identity has yet to be made in today’s Caribbean
political rhetoric, either at the regional or the national level.
The question then, is why hasn’t
this opportunity been grasped? I argue that there are three main reasons:
- A continued emphasis on national-level ideologies of
identity, as opposed to a true commitment to the creation of a regional
identity. This tendency can be attributed to two discrete but parallel
national-level factors. In some islands, Jamaica
being, I argue, the prime example, regionalism is not perceived as a
viable populist symbol of identity, and thus it is not emphasized. In
other CARICOM member states, primarily Trinidad and
Guyana,
there are strong, what we might call “Indo-centric”, sentiments that
reject what they perceive as the dominant Afro- or Creole-centric identity
of the regional integration movement. Those who hold these perceptions and
attitudes tend to be suspicious that the
regional integration movement is one in which their own
Indo-Caribbean identity is at best subsumed and at worst eradicated (Ryan
1999). Hence at the national level there is ambivalence about regional
integration, despite the plethora of summits, agreements and commitments
to regionalism.
- The existence of an inter-island rivalry among the Caribbean
business elite that dates back to the 1960s and 1970s. This is an area for
which more research must be undertaken, but there is a popular sentiment,
certainly in Jamaica,
that the situation of Trinidadian and Barbadian business expansion in the
late 1990s and early 2000s is “unfair” given the closure of those
economies to Jamaicans in previous decades. This thus leads to a rejection
of the Trinidadian banks as “regional” banks. The extent to which this
perception is held at the level of the political elite is also an area of
further research.
- A change in the perception of a bank as a symbol of
national identity in those countries where the banks are no longer under
national control. It is debatable why this change has come about. Is it
because the banks have escaped national control and there is no realistic
prospect of them returning to national control, and thus it is a pragmatic
change in attitude? Or, has there been a shift in ideology that no longer
sees banks as nationalist institutions, but as necessary service providers
whose owners’ nationality should be of no concern?
Analysis
By examining the banking sector in the
English-speaking Caribbean over the last 50 years, one can discern three main
features:
- Banks in the Caribbean have
been used as symbols of national identity, sovereignty and control over a
nation’s development;
- Ownership of banks in most Caribbean
countries has gone from post-independence nationalization and individual
national, usually government ownership, with some foreign ownership, to a
general trend of Canadian and Trinidadian ownership, with only a few small
nationally owned banks.
- The more recent changes, to the present scenario as
just described, have taken place without government direction, but rather
have been market-driven.
From the experience and trajectory
of the banking sector in the Caribbean, I argue that the
construction of identity, both national and regional, is subject to the
vagaries of individual CARICOM members’ political rhetoric regarding national
identity at the local level. Nationalistic symbols that were once apt for
political manipulation are discarded once those symbols change as a result of
external forces, or forces that are beyond the control of the national
government. However, while external conditions may change, the core
post-independence emphasis on national identity does not change, it only adapts
to the new environment by abandoning old symbols and focusing on new ones.
At the
beginning of the 21st century, that powerful symbol of identity of
the past, the banking sector, has become one of the most regionalized
businesses in the Caribbean, without the input or impetus of Caribbean governments. Further regionalization and
expansion of regional financial services and institutions, not only banks, is
impeded by national laws and prudential regulations of individual countries.
These impediments include obstacles to the free movement of capital, to the
right of enterprises to establish outside their home base, and to the ownership
of real property under the Alien Landholdings Act. All of these issues are on
the agenda for Caribbean governments to attend to (Bissember 2003). There is also an important barrier that
continues to be discussed among regional decision-makers but that has not yet
been materially altered on a regional basis, despite over a decade of
discussion and promises, which is the free movement of labour. It is difficult
to take CARICOM governments’ promises seriously when the first real move
towards truly liberalizing the movement of persons within the region only came
in 2003 when it became clear that this would be necessary to facilitate the
smooth running of the 2007 Cricket World Cup.
The
complete liberalization of the banking sector would appear inevitable given
global and regional trends. The initial stage of liberalization, since the
mid-1980s, has led to increased competition and profitability in the financial
sector in the Caribbean (Williams 1996). One might also argue
that it has led to greater transparency, particularly in the case of Jamaica after the 1996 crisis. There may be the
concern that with the further relaxation of barriers to entry, Caribbean countries will then be open to the true
financial giants that have swept much of Latin America, including the Dominican Republic. Yet here the Caribbean presents an unusual case in the current
global context. The English-speaking Caribbean
banking market, however enormously profitable it may be for the Canadian banks
that are already here, is too small and too saturated to be worthwhile for any
of the current expansionist giants, such as Banco Santander Central Hispano, or
Citibank North America. As Bissember points out,
given the pattern of the banking sector in the past few years, the removal of
both financial and non-financial sector restrictions could likely, “see
the creation of a truly CARICOM transnational corporation financed by regional
financial resources” (2003).
There of course remains the fact that, as
well as the new Trinidadian banking powers are doing, the Caribbean
banking sector remains heavily dominated by Canadian banks. According to CARICOM’s figures, without distinction for type of bank, in
2002 there were 94 banks in the region of which 39 were locally owned and ten
CARICOM (i.e. Trinidadian) owned. The remaining banks were owned by foreign
entities mainly from Canada,
and, to a much lesser extent, the U.S.,
via Citibank. Many of these Canadian banks, however, are partially owned by Caribbean
people, as a result of the localization programmes of the 1970s. Including
shareholders’ stakes, local and regional ownership ranges from 56% of the banks
in Barbados
and Guyana,
to 62% in Jamaica,
and close to 85% in Trinidad
and Tobago (Bissember
2003).
Regardless of nationality, however, it is
inarguably the case that all privately-owned banks have the same main objective:
increased profits for shareholders. That they are profit-oriented does not
mean, however, that they cease to be civic-minded, or to invest in
“developmental” projects that do not promise a worthwhile return on capital,
whether on their own initiative, or with prodding from the government.
Furthermore, financial institutions have many incentives beyond profit to need
to maintain good relations with the government, for their own benefit. They
also need to be seen as good corporate citizens by their customers, and thus
are unlikely to ignore the public relations benefits of their involvement in
certain projects. Finally, it is in the banks’ long-term interest to invest in
low-yield development projects, as the overall health and stability of the
economy only redounds to their own benefit. Indeed, many banks, at least in Jamaica,
factor non-profitable loans and investments in public works-type projects into
their cost structure, as a part of the cost of doing business in a heavily
politicized environment.
Conclusion
In the Caribbean,
the banking sector has consolidated, as it has throughout the world. In the
late 1960s and early 1970s the bank market structure was virtually controlled
by British and Canadian banks. By the mid 1980s the banking sectors of many Caribbean
countries showed significant market share by nationally owned, most public,
banks. In the early 1990s, especially in Jamaica
and Trinidad, there was a strong presence of nationally
owned private retail banks. By the late 1990s and into the early 2000s, the
ownership pattern of banks in the Caribbean had changed
significantly, so that today the largest market share in the English-speaking Caribbean
is held by Canadian and Trinidadian majority-owned and controlled banks.
While the current ownership
structure of the banking sector would suggest that English speaking Caribbean
countries are moving towards a consolidated regional financial sector, these
facts have not been incorporated into the political rhetoric at the national or
regional level. This examination of the banking sector in the Caribbean
supports the proposition that the construction of a Caribbean
regional identity will not come about if left to Caribbean
governments. CARICOM governments have yet to make good on their repeated
commitments to regional integration and the construction of a regional
identity, even where opportunities to capitalize on existing regional
institutions, such as banks, exist. They are still too concerned with
island-specific definitions of and debates over national identity, despite the
ever-tightening noose around the possibilities to promote these ideas.
Nationalism and identity, after all, provide one last tool with which
governments and political movements can rally public support and capture the
people’s imagination, in a global political and economic context where little
else is available for this purpose.
Endnotes
[1] This factor is especially significant after the
mid-1990s, as even in countries like Chile and Argentina where the banking
sector had been relatively open for a decade or more, foreign banks only went
there as part of a general Latin America expansion.
[2] This
meant that branches of foreign banks had to convert themselves into domestic
firms, and new direct foreign investment was prohibited. Due to loopholes in
the law, however, control of the joint-ownership banks that were permitted
ended up in foreign hands.
[3] “National champions” are those large, regionally or
even internationally competitive, private banks that are still owned by
nationals of the developing country in which the bank is operating. In some
developing countries where foreign banks have begun to dominate the retail
banking market, there is a “national champion” that is still managing to hold
its own. In some cases, the national champion is even expanding, making
acquisitions alongside the foreign banks’ acquisitions.
[4] For Latin
America, for example, see Kessler 1999; Neiman Auerbach
2001; and Marichal 1997. For Asia
see Lukauskas 2002 and Claessens
and Glaessner 1999. For Spain
and the former Eastern European socialist bloc see Pérez 1997, and Blejer and Škreb 1999,
respectively.
[5] Retail
banking is that part of commercial banking concerned with the activities of
individual customers, generally in large numbers (Smith and Walter 1997,
101).Retail banks are those which provide services such as checking accounts
(demand deposits), and consumer debit and credit cards.
[6] Raymond Forrest, “No requiem for Workers Bank,” The Financial Gleaner, 18 January 1991.
[7] “Big
Bank Merger in Offing.” Insight IX
(2), December 1-15, 1992,
p. 8.
[8] The “21
families” refers to a commonly held perception that in Jamaica
a handful of people, commonly called the oligarchy of the 21 families, are able
to command and control the resources of the country for their exclusive use
because of their wealth and access to the corridors of power.
[9] Neville Spike, “The oligarchy and privatization,” The Gleaner 2 February 1992, p. 20.
[10] Paul
Chen-Young, as quoted in Franklyn 2001, p. 39.
[11] Henley Morgan, “Dr Davies' mea culpa,” Jamaica Observer, 25 October 2002.
[12] Girod Bank was established by a Puerto Rican entrepreneur
in Jamaica in
the mid-1980s.
[13]
Paget deFreitas, “The Making of
an Empire” The Gleaner 20 March 1992, p. 2.
[14] The Financial Gleaner, 16 October 1992, p. 7
[15] Henley
Morgan, “Dr Davies' mea culpa,” Jamaica Observer, 25
October 2002.
[16] True to McKinnon’s
hypothesis, Marion Williams’ comprehensive study later found that a liberalized
banking system in the Caribbean meant increased competitiveness, greater profitability,
and more availability of bank credit (1996).
[17] Foreign ownership of more than 20% of local banks was
prohibited under Andean Pact rules during 1971-1987.
[18] Up
until 2001, British Barclays still retained branches in 14 Caribbean
countries. They are expected to rebrand under the
First Caribbean name, since the merger with CIBC.
[19] AIC
originally stood for Advantage Investment Counsel, but is now known solely by
its acronym.
[20] See Bissember (2003) for a detailed account of RBTT and
Republic Bank’s recent regional expansion.
[21] Robert Norstrom, cited in, David Renwick,
“Unsettled Waters in the Caribbean.” The Banker 1 October 2002.
[22] I examined the work of the CARICOM Women’s Desk
(1997), and of the Master in International Business degree programme between
CARICOM, the Dominican
Republic
and Haiti (2000).
References
Amin, Samir. 1987. “Nationalism.”
The New Palgrave:
A Dictionary of Economics. Volume 3. London:
Palgrave.
Arun, T.G. and J.D. Turner. 2002. “Financial Sector Reforms
in Developing Countries: The Indian Experience.” The World Economy 25, 3 (March): 429-446.
Barajas Adolfo, Roberto Steiner, and Natalia Salazar. 2000.
“Foreign Investment in Colombia’s
Financial Sector.” Pp. 355-387 in The
Internationalization of Financial Services: Issues and Lessons for Developing
Countries, edited by Stijn Claessens
and Marion Jansen. The Hague: Kluwer Law International.
Baum,
Daniel Jay. 1974. The Banks of Canada in the Commonwealth Caribbean: Economic Nationalism and Multinational
Enterprises of a Medium Power. New York:
Praeger.
Beim, David O., and Charles W. Calomiris.
2001. Emerging Financial Markets. New
York: McGraw Hill.
Blejer, Mario I. and Marko Škreb. 1999. “Financial Reforms and Economic Transitions:
An Overview of the Major Issues.” Pp. 1-16 in Financial Sector Transformation: Lessons from Economies in Transition,
edited by Mario I. Blejer and Marko Škreb. Cambridge;
New York: Cambridge
University Press.
Bissember, Enid E. 2003. Protocol II of the CARICOM Single
Market and Economy: Implications for Banking and Finance. CARICOM Secretariat
Economic Intelligence and Policy Unit.
Block,
Fred. 1994. “The Roles of the State in the Economy.” Pp. 691-710 in The Handbook of Economic Sociology,
edited by Neil J. Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton, New
Jersey: Princeton
University Press.
Boxill, Ian. 1993. Ideology
and Caribbean Integration. Mona,
Jamaica: Consortium
Graduate School
of Social Sciences, with Canoe Press.
Bosworth,
Barry, Rudiger Dornbusch,
and Raúl Labán. 1994. The Chilean Economy: Policy Lessons and Challenges. Washington,
D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Brown,
Deryck R. 1989. History
of Money and Banking in Trinidad and Tobago from 1789-1989. Port
of Spain: Central Bank of Trinidad
and Tobago.
Brownbridge, Martin. 2002. “Banking reforms in Africa: What has
been learnt?” Insights
40 (March). Retrieved February 2, 2003 (http://www.id21.org/insights/insights40/insights-iss40-art01.html)
Claessens, Stijn, and Tom Glaessner. 1999. “Internationalization of Financial
Services in Asia.” Presented at the conference
Investment Liberalisation and Financial Reform in the
Asia-Pacific Region, August 29-31, Sydney, Australia.
Mimeo.
Coleman,
William D. 1996. Financial Services,
Globalization and Domestic Policy Change. Houndmills, England:
Macmillan Press.
Danns, Donna. 1996. “Financial Sector
Development in the Caribbean 1970-1995.” Paper presented
at the Monetary Studies Conference, Trinidad and
Tobago.
Denizer, Cevdet. 2000. “Foreign
Entry in Turkey’s
Banking Sector, 1980-97.” Mimeo.
Dookeran, Winston. 2002. “The Financial Liberalisation
Agenda: Performance and Prospects.” Pp. 429-441 in Caribbean Survival and the Global Challenge, edited by Ramesh Ramsaran. Kingston,
Jamaica: Ian Randle
Publishers.
Farrell,
Terrence W. 1993. “Banking in a (Rapidly) Changing World.” Address to Bank of Nova
Scotia Management Meeting. Port
of Spain, Trinidad. Mimeo.
Franklyn,
Delano. 2001. The Right Move: Corporate Leadership and Governance in Jamaica.
Kingston: Arawak
Press.
Gereffi, Gary. 1994. “The International Economy and
Economic Development.” Pp. 206-233 in The
Handbook of Economic Sociology, edited by Neil J. Smelser
and Richard Swedberg. Princeton,
New Jersey: Princeton
University Press.
Gereffi, Gary, and Peter Evans. 1995. “Transnational
Corporations, Dependent Development, and State Policy in the Semiperiphery: A Comparison of Brazil
and Mexico.”
Pp. 203-235 in Latin America’s Economic
Development: Confronting Crisis, edited by James L. Dietz. Boulder:
Lynne Rienner Publishers.
Girvan,
Norman. 2000. “Globalization and Counter-Globalization: The Caribbean
in the Context of the South.” Pp. 65-87 in Globalization
a Calculus of Inequality: Perspectives from the South, edited by Denis Benn
and Kenneth Hall. Kingston: Ian
Randle Publishers.
Guillén, Mauro F., and Adrian E. Tschoegl.
1999. “At Last the Internationalization of Retail Banking? The Case of the
Spanish Banks in Latin America.” Wharton Financial Institutions
Center Working Paper Series.
Retrieved April 7, 2002
<http://www.google.com/search?q=cache:_nIqgQaAowMC:wrdsenet.wharton.upenn.edu/fic/wfic/papers/99/9941.pdf+Guillen,+Mauro+and+Adrian+Tschoegl.+1999.+%93At+Last+the+Internationalization+of+Retail+Banking%3F+&hl=en&lr=lang_en%7Clang_fr%7Clang_es>.
Hoffman,
Susan. 2001. Politics and Banking: Ideas,
Public Policy and the Creation of Financial Institutions. Baltimore:
The Johns Hopkins
University Press.
International
Monetary Fund (IMF). 2000. World Economic
and Financial Surveys. International Capital Markets: Developments, Prospects,
and Key Policy Issues.
Washington, D.C.:
International Monetary Fund.
July,
Peter. 1995. “Rise of the Formal Institution of Banking in the Community.” CARICOM
Perspective 65, July, 91-3.
Kessler,
Timothy. 1999. Global Capital and
National Politics: Reforming Mexico’s Financial System. Westport,
Connecticut: Praeger
Publishers.
Knox,
Paul, and John Agnew. 1998. The Geography
of the World Economy: An Introduction to Economic Geography, 3rd
edition. London: Arnold.
Lindgren,
Carl-Johan, Gillian Garcia and Matthew I. Saal. 1996.
Bank Soundness and Macroeconomic Policy.
Washington, D.C.:
International Monetary Fund.
Lue Lim, Gail. 1991. “Jamaica’s
Financial System: Its Historical Development.” Kingston:
Bank of Jamaica.
Lukauskas, Arvid. 2002.
“Financial Restriction and the Developmental State in East Asia:
Toward a More Complex Political Economy.” Comparative
Political Studies 35 (4), May, 379-412.
Makler, Harry and Walter L. Ness, Jr. 2002. “How Financial
Intermediation Challenges National Sovereignty in Emerging Markets.” Quarterly
Review of Economics & Finance, 42 (5), Winter, 827-51.
Marichal, Carlos. 1997. “Nation
Building and the Origins of Banking
in Latin America, 1850-1930.” Pp. 339-377 in Banking, Trade and Industry: Europe, America
and Asia from the Thirteenth to the Twentieth Century, edited by Alice Teichova, Ginette Kurgan-Van Hentenryk and Dieter Ziegler. Cambridge,
England: Cambridge
University Press.
McKinnon,
Ronald. 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington,
D.C.: Brookings Institution.
Milner,
Helen V. and Robert O. Keohane. 1996. “Introduction.”
Pp. 3-24 in Internationalization and
Domestic Politics, edited by Robert O. Keohane
and Helen V. Milner. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Mizruchi, Mark S., and Linda Brewster Stearns. 1994.
“Money, Banking and Financial Markets.” Pp. 313-341 in The Handbook of Economic Sociology, edited by Neil J. Smelser and Richard Swedberg. Princeton,
New Jersey: Princeton
University Press.
Murinde, Victor. 2001. “Does Africa need foreign banks?” Africa
Online. Retrieved February 2, 2003
<http://www.africaonline.com/site/Articles/1,3,46765.jsp>.
Neiman
Auerbach, Nancy.
2001. States, Banks and Markets: Mexico’s Path to Financial Liberalization in
Comparative Perspective. Boulder, Colorado:
Westview Press.
Pérez.
Sofía A. 1997. Banking
on Privilege: The Politics of Spanish Financial Reform. Ithaca,
New York: Cornell
University Press.
Pomerleano, Michael, and George J. Vojta.
2001. “What do Foreign Banks Do in Emerging Markets? An Institutional Study.”
Presented at the World Bank, International Monetary Fund and Brookings
Institution 3rd Annual Financial Markets and Development Conference,
Open Doors: Foreign Participation in Financial Systems in Developing Countries.
April 19-21, New York.
Ramkisson, Ronald. 2002. “Globalisation
and the Caribbean Financial Sector: Toward a Strategy
for Survival.” Pp. 455-464 in Caribbean
Survival and the Global Challenge, edited by Ramesh
Ramsaran. Kingston, Jamaica:
Ian Randle Publishers.
Ryan,
Selwyn. 1999. “East Indians, West Indians and the Quest for Caribbean
Political Unity.” Social and Economic
Studies 48 (4), December, 151-184.
Smith,
Roy C., and Ingo Walter. 1997. Global
Banking. New York: Oxford
University Press.
Thomas,
Clive. 1966. “Imperial Monetary Arrangements and the Caribbean.”
New World Fortnightly 49 (December). Reprinted in
Readings in the Political Economy of the
Caribbean, compiled and edited by Norman Girvan and Owen Jefferson, New
World Press.
Thorburn,
Diana. 1997. “Gender, Regionalism, and Caribbean
Development: An Examination of CARICOM Policy.” M.Sc.
Thesis, Institute of International
Relations, University of the West
Indies, St. Augustine, Trinidad
and Tobago.
_____________.
2000. “A Reformed Public Sector in an Integrated Caribbean
in the 21st Century? Some preliminary results from a project with
these goals.” Paper presented at the 2000 Congress of the Latin American
Studies Association, Miami, Florida.
Williams,
Marion V. 1996. Liberalising a Regulated Banking System: The Caribbean Case.
Hants, England:
Avebury.
________________.
2002. “Implications of Liberalisation for Commercial
Banking in the Caribbean.” Pp. 442-455 in Caribbean Survival and the Global Challenge,
edited by Ramesh Ramsaran. Kingston,
Jamaica: Ian Randle
Publishers.
Worrell,
DeLisle. 1983. “Banking in Barbados,
1960-82.” Central Bank of Barbados.
October. Mimeo.
Wright,
Winthrop R. 1974. British-Owned Railways in Argentina: Their Effect on Economic Nationalism,
1854-1948. Austin: University
of Texas Press.
Zysman, John. 1983. Government,
Markets and Growth: Financial Systems and the Politics of Industrial Change.
Ithaca, New York:
Cornell University
Press.